사이드바 영역으로 건너뛰기

'분류 전체보기'에 해당되는 글 110건

  1. 2008/03/22 Paul Davidson on the US subprime-led financial crisis
  2. 2007/11/01 Robert Wade on current US credit turmoil
  3. 2007/08/22 Market Bondage (T. Palley)
  4. 2007/08/22 Money markets hit reverse (FT)
  5. 2007/07/29 FT Bridging poverty gap should be IMF priority
  6. 2007/07/29 FT Brazil claims WTO cotton victory
  7. 2007/07/13 Jagdish Bhagwati - US Senate Finance Committee Testimony
  8. 2007/07/13 CALLS FOR IMF LEADERSHIP REFORMS
  9. 2007/07/13 TPA Expires
  10. 2007/06/19 Krugman on Trade and Inequality

Newer Entries Older Entries

Paul Davidson on the US subprime-led financial crisis

View Comments

HOW TO SOLVE THE U.S. HOUSING PROBLEM AND AVOID
A RECESSION:a revived holc and rtc

Paul Davidson

Paul Davidson is a Visiting Scholar at the Schwartz Center for Economic Policy Analysis (SCEPA) and Editor of the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics.

Within the last few months, the so-called “subprime mortgage crisis” has developed from a small blip on the economic radar screen to a situation that has threatened financial markets and financial institutions worldwide. This financial instability induced the Federal Reserve to announce a historically large 75 basis point decline in the federal funds rate on January 22, 2008. Financial experts and economists are suddenly talking of a U.S. recession in 2008, and the only question is how deep the depressing effects will be. There is even the possibility of a global recession. This recessionary threat has led the White House and Congress to announce a fiscal stimulus package consisting primarily of a one-time tax rebate of between $300 to $1200 for families within defined income limits, plus a temporary tax reduction for business making certain investments in 2008. This stimulus plan is surely too little and too late.

Just a little over a month ago, many of the “best and the brightest” economic experts were not in favor of any fiscal stimulus package. The Wall Street Journal reported that former Federal Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan recommended that politicians do nothing to prevent a possible recession as a result of the subprime mortgage lending mess.1 Greenspan preferred to let the market solve the problem by “letting housing prices (and security pegged to mortgages) fall until investors see them as bargains and start buying, stabilizing the economy.” But if Congress does nothing, then a year from today we may be mired in the Greatest Recession since the Great Depression.

The proposed stimulus package will bring forth some additional household and business spending. Nevertheless, perhaps as much as 20 percent of each dollar of household tax rebate will go to buy cheap foreign imported goods, and therefore will not stimulate demand for American produced goods. Another 20 to 30 percent of household rebates may go into reducing household credit card or other debts, or directly into savings accounts. Accordingly, perhaps as little as fifty cents on the dollar will stimulate the economy. Not much stimulus bang for the buck!

The temporary tax cuts for businesses may not stimulate much additional investment as long as domestic market demand remains slack. Moreover, since the business tax relief is temporary, it encourages moving investments that may already be scheduled for next year into today’s tax reduction period, thus creating a potential further decline in demand after the tax relief expires. In sum, any temporary fiscal stimulus package is likely to have temporary, and small if any, positive effects to offset the forthcoming recession in 2008.

As I will discuss below, the original subprime mess has ultimately resulted in an insolvency problem for millions of U.S. households. The government’s fiscal “stimulus” plan does not directly address this insolvency problem. The Federal Reserve pumping in more liquidity will not end the housing insolvency problem. Instead, I suggest a tried and true comprehensive program to create a major federal facility to refinance mortgages at low rates and extended maturities, and to finance new investment in private sector housing.

The goal of this new lending facility will be to: 1) end the insolvency housing problem; 2) avoid a serious recession, and; 3) prevent similar financial bubbles due to securitization of loan-backed financial assets from developing in the future.

BANK SOLVENCY CRISES

A sage once said “Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat its errors.” So let’s look at what history can teach us about what “caused” this housing bubble and how we can relieve the distress. After U.S. Stock Market Crash of October 1929, one out of every five banks in the U.S. failed.

Several years after the Crash and the beginning of The Great Depression of the 1930s, a U.S. Senate committee held hearings on the possible causes of the Crash. These hearings indicated that in the early part of the 20th century individual investors were seriously hurt by banks whose self-interest lay in promoting sales of securities that benefited only the banks. The hearings concluded that a major cause of the Crash was that banks, in the 1920s, significantly increased their underwriting activities of securities. Consequently, in 1933, Congress passed the Glass-Steagall Act, which banned banks from underwriting securities. Financial institutions had to choose either to be a simple bank lender or an underwriter (investment banker or brokerage firm). The Act also gave the Federal Reserve more control over banking activities.

As a result, for several decades bank originated mortgage loans were not resalable. The originating bank lender knew that he or she would have to carry the mortgage loan debt security over its life. If the borrower defaulted, the lender would bear the costs of foreclosure. Thus, the originating bank lender thoroughly investigated the three C’s of each borrower—Collateral, Credit History, and Character—before making a mortgage loan.

In the 1970s, deregulation of U.S. banking activities began when brokerage firms began offering money market, high interest, check writing accounts that competed with traditional banking business. In the 1980s the Federal Reserve reinterpreted the Glass-Steagall Act to allow banks to engage in securities underwriting activities to a small extent. In 1987 the Fed Board allowed banks to handle significant underwriting activities including those of mortgage-backed securities, despite objections of Fed Chairman Paul Volker. When Alan Greenspan became chair of the Fed in 1987, he favored further bank deregulation to help U.S. banks compete with foreign banks, where the latter are often universal banks which are permitted to act as investment banks, take equity stakes, and the like.

In 1996, the Federal Reserve permitted bank holding companies to own investment banking affiliates that could contribute up to 25 percent of total revenue of the holding company. In 1999, after 12 attempts in 25 years, Congress (with the support of President Clinton) repealed the Glass-Steagall Act. In a 1999 article in The Wall Street Journal (a few days before Congress repealed the Act), Republican Senator Phil Gramm is quoted as telling a Citigroup lobbyist to “get [Citigroup Co-Chairman] Sandy Weill on the phone right now. Tell him to call the White House and get [them] moving.”2 Soon after Gramm’s warning, President Clinton supported the repeal of the Glass-Steagall. Shortly after Congress repealed the Act, Secretary of Treasury Robert Rubin accepted a top job at Citigroup.

Housing market crises in history

Once Glass-Steagall was repealed, there were no legal constraints between loan origination and underwriting activities. Accordingly, there is a great profit incentive for a mortgage originator to search out any potential home buyers (including sub prime ones) and provide them with a mortgage. The originator can then profitably sell these mortgages, usually within 30 days, to an underwriter, or act as an underwriter to sell to the public exotic mortgage-backed securities. The originator therefore has no fear of default if the borrower can at least make his first monthly mortgage payment.

The underwriter typically packages these mortgages into collateral debt obligations (CDOs), Structured Investment Vehicles (SIVs), or other esoteric financial vehicles. He then sells tranches in these vehicles to unwary pension funds, local and state revenue funds, individual investors, or other banks domestically or overseas (e.g., Northern Rock in the UK) who, led on by the high ratings of these complex financial securities by rating agencies, believe these are safe investment vehicles. Thus, since the turn of the century, this process of packaging and selling mortgage-backed securities has helped finance the housing bubble that pushed housing prices to historic highs by 2005.

In a December 14, 2007 article, New York Times op-ed writer Paul Krugman defined the resulting housing bubble as where the price of housing exceeded a “normal ratio” relative to rents or incomes.3 Like Greenspan, Krugman does not suggest anything that politicians can do to relieve the distress caused by the deflating housing bubble. Krugman believes the market will solve the problem by deflating house prices. He estimates that housing prices will have to fall by 30 percent to restore a “normal ratio.” This implies that home values in the U.S. will decline by some six trillion dollars.

The result will be that many borrowers “will find themselves with negative equity” as their outstanding mortgage exceeds this “normal” market price of the borrower’s house—an insolvency problem. Krugman indicates that no one can provide a quick fix for this problem; he suggests that it will “take years” for the market to clean up the insolvency housing mess.

In many states mortgages are non-recourse loans (i.e., after default and foreclosure the borrower is not responsible for the difference between the outstanding mortgage balance and the lower sale price at foreclosure). If Krugman’s 30 percent house value decline is accurate, as many as 10 million
households will end up with negative equity and will have a strong incentive to default. Millions of homeowners
will lose their homes in foreclosure proceedings and investors in mortgage-backed securities will incur large losses.

The holc

But a study of history can give us clues as to how to solve the problem. The Roosevelt Administration’s handling of the housing insolvency crisis of the 1930s suggests a precedent for dealing with the U.S. housing bubble distress. In 1933, the Home Owners Refinancing Act created the Home Owners’ Loan Corporation (HOLC) to refinance homes to prevent foreclosures, and also to bail out mortgage holding banks. The HOLC was a tremendous success, making one million low-interest loans which often extended the pay-off period of the original loan, thereby significantly reducing the monthly payments to amounts that homeowners could afford. In its years of operation, the HOLC not only paid all its bills, but it also made a small profit.

Other measures might include setting up a government agency to take non-performing mortgage loans off the books of private balance sheets and therefore remove the threat of insolvency for those who took positions in the mortgage-backed securities after being misled by rating agencies. The result will prevent further sell-offs causing financial distress in all financial markets. The Resolution Trust Corporation, set up by the government, did remove non-performing mortgage loans from Building Societies’ balance sheets after the 1980s Savings and Loan bank crisis, thereby preventing further financial damage to others. Also, Congress might consider a 21st Century version of the 1930s government-sponsored Reconstruction Finance Corporation to help finance investments and operations in the private sector housing and related industries during this insolvency crisis.
Congress should act promptly to create the necessary government agencies to help clean up this mess rather than wait out the “years” that Krugman suggests it would take if we leave the solution to the market. Moreover, the Greenspan-Krugman market solution will cause collateral damage to many innocent economic casualties (e.g., homeowners in neighborhoods where foreclosures are prevalent, and workers and business firms in construction and related industries).

While we wait for Congress to act on this proposed program, it may be desirable for the Federal government to start up an infrastructure rebuilding program to help stimulate the economy out of a potential forthcoming recession and increase productivity in the longer run. There is sufficient evidence that more than 50 percent of U.S. bridges and other public structures are in a weakened or failing condition. What better way to offset a possible recession in the construction industry and at the same time contribute to improvements in our nation’s transportation productivity? Every dollar spent on rebuilding and improving infrastructure will create jobs for U.S. workers and profits for domestic enterprises.

RESPONSE TO POTENTIAL NAY-SAYERS

There will be those who say that this proposed solution to the housing bubble problem will be too costly. Moreover, they will question why U.S. taxpayers should bail out banks, other financial institutions, individual investors, and individual subprime borrowers who made foolish decisions. To help these institutions and individuals will merely introduce the “moral hazard” problem: protecting individuals and institutions from economic losses they would otherwise suffer due to their previous foolish decisions will only encourage them (and other fools) to make more risky decisions in the future since, if their actions result in large economic losses, they believe the government will step in to bail them out. What is the proper response to nay-sayers who raise these arguments?

First, the real cost of a serious recession in 2008 is very large if we do nothing but hope that the Federal Reserve continues to lower the interest rate that they charge banks. The above proposal assures that, at worst, a mild slow down will occur in 2008, and more likely the U.S. economy will experience substantial economic growth while rebuilding productive infrastructure. Clearly these benefits exceed the potential real costs of a recession that could last several years.

Second, this proposal avoids the significant collateral economic damage to many innocent bystanders that will occur if we rely on the market to reduce home prices by 30 percent. These innocent bystanders include: 1) existing homeowners, especially in areas where there are large number of neighborhood foreclosures; 2) potential home buyers who have deposits on unfinished homes where builders file for bankruptcy (The New York Times recently featured a front-page article about this regarding Levitt Builders in the Carolinas4 ); 3) unemployed workers and businesses in the building and home furnishing industries; 4) local governments that put their revenues into CDOs thinking that their money was in a safe investment, and; 5) some pensioners who might find their annual pension income declining as the pension fund takes a loss on its investment in mortgage-backed assets.

If this proposal is adopted, which banks will be bailed out? Probably very few banks, except the large ones who have combined normal banking affiliates with investment banking underwriting subsidiaries under the banking holding company cloak (e.g., Citigroup). There are news reports that upon occasion these big institutions provided some “liquidity puts”( i.e., promised to buy back some tranches of their asset-backed packages), which means that if financial stress occurs, these banks’ off-balance sheet liabilities might have to be moved back to on-balance sheet of the bank and/or its underwriting affiliate. That partly explains the big write-offs of Morgan Stanley, Merrill Lynch, etc. But these big bank institutions are “too big to fail” anyway, so some bailout must be arranged. Small regional banks often are not big enough to engage in significant underwriting activities. If, however, they did create mortgage-backed assets that they sold to the public, then the liability of default has probably already been passed off without any “liquidity put” guarantees.

The last refuge of those who argue against bailout is the “moral hazard” argument. But if Congress passes a 21st Century equivalent of the Glass-Steagall Act, which prohibits making bank loans resalable, then we will have legally prevented those who have been bailed out from again originating risky loans that they can push off their balance sheets within a month or so.

History also tells us that the distress to U.S. taxpayers for extensive bail-out programs is not significant. Did most taxpayers notice any significant cost of resolving the S&L crisis, despite the media’s constant argument that taxpayers would suffer? Did individual and corporate income tax rates increase as a direct result of the S&L problem?

THE FALLACY OF THE TAXPAYER COST QUESTION

The question of taxpayer costs for bailouts of financial institutions is typically part of discussions by the mass media. The question “what is it going to cost the U.S. taxpayer?” reflects an unthinking bias against active government policies to prevent recession and depression. Asking how much an active government policy to prevent a financial market calamity is going to cost the taxpayer can only be based on an economic theory that assumes that the macroeconomic activity in the economy will be unchanged whether or not the government takes any positive action to remove distress in financial markets. In other words, underlying this question is the micro theory ceteris paribus assumption—where the ceteris paribus is that the nation’s GDP will, in the long run, follow an unchanging long-run permanent full employment trend line.

Accordingly, if there is a recession due to some financial distress, it is conceived as representing an X percent fall below this trend line for a period of time before some automatic market mechanism restores the economy to the predetermined full employment trend line. If, on the other hand, the government takes some positive policy action to resolve the housing insolvency finance problem, then, it is presumed, there must be a Y percent taxpayer cost deduction from the trend line. When the problem is framed in this rhetoric, then it appears obvious that one should compare the magnitudes of X percent vis-à-vis Y percent reduction from the trend line. If Y percent is greater than X percent, then no government action should be taken.

Since the cost of a forthcoming recession cannot be accurately predicted except after the fact, while one can always make some estimate of the cost of operating a government program, it should be obvious that the government plan can always be painted as larger than the cost of a mild recession. Consequently, the rhetoric of this cost to taxpayer question will almost always favor the “do nothing” argument, because it assumes that the economy has some automatic market mechanism that assures that the GDP will always quickly return to a full employment level of GDP.

In the real world, however, there is no predetermined, long-run GDP full employment trend line. The macroeconomic performance of the U.S. economy will be substantially improved in both the short- and long-run if the government takes direct action. If, on the other hand, the government leaves it to the market to solve the problem, the result will be an economic recession that might even collapse into a depression. Consequently, the income of American taxpayers will, on average, be significantly improved if government takes action than if we rely on the market to solve such problems. If the government does nothing, U.S. residents stand to experience a severe reduction to their income levels. Accordingly, a properly designed policy to avoid financial and economic depression provides only benefits—not costs—to the nation’s economy.

Let us look at a historical example where if this type of “what will cost to the tax payer and/or the economy?” question were asked, one of the most desirable government policies would never have been undertaken. At the Bretton Woods conference it was recognized that the European nations would need significant aid to help rebuild their economies after the war. Keynes estimated that the need would be between $12 and $15 billion. U.S. representative Harry Dexter White indicated that Congress could not ask the taxpayers to provide more than $3 billion. Accordingly, the Keynes Plan was defeated at Bretton Woods, and the Dexter White proposals were adopted

Suppose that in 1946 it was recommended that U.S. give a gift of $13 billion dollars over four years to various European countries to help them rebuild their war-ravaged economies (in 1940s current dollars, this sum would be well over $150 billion in 2007 dollars). Obviously if Dexter White was correct, the Congress would never have approved the Marshall Plan. Since the Marshall Plan did not reveal in advance that it would provide foreign governments $13 billion over a period of four years, Congress approved the Marshall Pan. The Marshall Plan gave foreign nations approximately two percent of the United States’ GDP each year for four years. Was the Marshall Plan costly to U.S. taxpayers and the U.S. economy?

The statistics indicate that, during the Marshall Plan years, for the first time in history the U.S. did not experience a serious economic slowdown immediately after a war. And this despite the fact that federal government expenditures on goods and services declined by approximately 57 percent between 1945 and 1946. Furthermore, four years after World War II, federal government expenditure was still approximately half of what it had been in 1945.

When the U.S. emerged from World War II, the federal debt was more than 100 percent of the GDP. Accordingly, there was great political pressure to reign in federal government spending to make sure that the federal debt did not grow substantially. Clearly, then, it was not “Keynesian” deficit spending that kept the U.S. out of recession in the immediate post-World War II years.

What was the cost of the Marshall Plan to the U.S. economy and the U.S. taxpayer? In 1946, the GDP per capita was 25 percent higher than it had been in the last peace years before the War. GDP per capita continued to grow during the Marshall Plan years. Despite giving away two percent of U.S. GDP, American residents (and taxpayers) experienced a higher standard of living each year.

Clearly The Marshall Plan did not make American taxpayers feel they were bearing a great cost in terms of real income. The Marshall Plan was good for the European nations since the Europeans used the funds to buy U.S. exports needed to feed its population and rebuild it war damaged capital stock. In the United States, unemployment was not a problem despite nine million men and women being released from the Armed Services into the civilian population and labor force. The Marshall Plan financed a significant growth in U.S. exports that help offset, in part, the fall in aggregate demand due to a reduction in government spending. U.S. export growth was not the only offset as pent up consumer demand also expanded in the post-war period. Without the Marshall Plan, however, the U.S. export industries would not have expanded, and probably would have declined, as European nations exhausted whatever foreign reserves they possessed.

In sum, were there any real costs of the Marshall Plan as compared to doing nothing? A response that Americans were forced to reduce their living standards by approximately two percent would only be correct if one assumed that the GDP would have been the same in those early post-war years without the Marshall Plan. Can anyone really believe this?

THE ACCOUNTING COSTS OF INSTITUTIONS SUCH AS HOLC AND RTC

It has already been indicated that the HOLC actually earned a small profit over its life. From 1933 to 1935, the HOLC provided almost $3 billion in bonds to banks in exchange for mortgages, thereby reducing the pressure of potential economic failure for many banks. Moreover, if it were not for the HOLC more houses would have been foreclosed. The economic misery of the depression would have been worse. More Americans would have been living in the street (or Hoovervilles), while the U.S. housing stock would have depreciated much more rapidly due to the neglect of vacant foreclosed homes.

The HOLC financed all of its operations through either earnings or borrowing. Congress never appropriated any funds for the HOLC. [Notice this made the operations of HOLC an off-balance sheet operation.] The original act called for the HOLC to issue its own bonds with the interest guaranteed by the U.S. Treasury and with a maturity not to exceed 18 years. A year later the guarantee by the Treasury was extended to the principal as well. Although HOLC initially issued its bonds to the public, eventually the HOLC received its funds by borrowing directly from the Treasury rather than from the money markets. From 1936 to 1940, HOLC borrowed $875 million directly from the U.S. Treasury.

The RTC was a corporation formed by Congress in 1989 to replace the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation and to respond to the insolvency of about 750 savings and loan associations. As receiver, it sold assets of failed S&Ls and paid insured depositors. In 1995 its duties, including insurance of deposit in thrift institutions, were transferred to the Savings Association Insurance Fund.

The S&L crisis in 1989 occurred under a Republican Administration that had pledged “no new taxes.” Nevertheless, the Administration recognized the difficulty of the problem involving the large number of S&L insolvencies, and it supported the formation of the RTC. The first Bush administration recognized, apparently, that the RTC would not require new taxes to burden the U.S. taxpayer with the cost of the program.

After much wrangling by Congress, the initial funding of the RTC included $18.8 billion from the Treasury and $31.2 billion from bonds issued by the RTC (and therefore an-off budget liability). In 1995, the RTC was folded into another larger government agency, and there has been no public accounting records provided to show whether the RTC operations ultimately made a profit or not.

In sum, although there are some accounting costs of setting up any institution similar to the HOLC and the RTC, these bookkeeping entries are unlikely to hurt U.S. taxpayers. The benefits from having such institutions alleviating economic distress far outweigh the costs of allowing deflationary market forces solve the problem of our bursting housing and financial bubble.

notes
1. Wessel, David. (2007). “Don’t Count On A Stimulus Plan.” The Wall Street Journal, December 20, 2007.
2. Schroeder, Michael. (1999). “Glass-Steagall Accord Reached After Last Minute Deal Making.” The Wall Street Journal, October 25, 1999.
3. Krugman, Paul. (2007). “After The Money’s Gone.” The New York Times, December 14, 2007.
4. Streitfeld, David. (2008). “With Builder in Bankruptcy, Buyers Are Left Out.” The New York Times, January 3, 2008.
진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2008/03/22 15:58 2008/03/22 15:58

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Robert Wade on current US credit turmoil

View Comments

logo
Published on openDemocracy (http://www.opendemocracy.net)

The financial crisis: burst bubble, frayed model

Created 2007-10-01 16:00

As everyone now knows, the current financial market turmoil spreading across the Atlantic economy and beyond started with rising defaults in the United States mortgage market. How did the US come to experience a gigantic house-price bubble?


The explanation starts with US trade deficits and their financing. The US has been running an increasing trade (or more accurately, current-account) deficit since the early 1980s, with only one short interruption. The excess of imports over exports is paid for by newly printed dollars or Treasury [1] bonds.


In countries running trade surpluses (like China and Japan [2]), exporters to the US sell their dollars to their banks in return for domestic currency. This increases the demand for domestic currency, which - if the central bank does not intervene - tends to appreciate in value. As the currency appreciates, so too does the wage level, which impairs the economy's competitiveness. So to maintain export competitiveness and to boost employment, the central banks buy the dollars from exporters in return for newly created domestic currency; this functions as high-powered money - increasing domestic demand, raising the ratio of "financial" to "real" transactions, and encouraging speculation in domestic and foreign assets.


At the same time, the central banks use their increasing stock of dollars to invest [3] in US assets in order to earn a return. The return flow pushes up asset values in the US, including property and Treasury bonds. Higher bond prices go with lower yields, and therefore lower interest rates. Lower interest rates push up US consumption, US domestic debt and US imports, and cause the US deficit [4] to grow even bigger. 

But when the central banks invest in US assets like Treasury bonds (using the dollars they have bought from exporters), their action puts downward pressure on the dollar, which, other things being equal, tends to reduce the deficit. Lower bond yields (due to higher price of bonds) mean that other investors are less inclined to buy dollars with which to invest in Treasury bonds, so the lower yields produce a lower dollar.  In fact, lower yields may cause some foreign investors to sell the Treasury bonds they already hold and then sell the dollars they receive to buy some other currency with higher yields, adding to downward pressure on the dollar.

Robert Wade is professor of political economy at the London School of Economics. He worked as a World Bank economist in the 1980s. He is the author of Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asia's Industrialization [5] (Princeton University Press, 1990) and of "Is globalization reducing poverty and inequality?", in John Ravenhill, ed., Global Political Economy [6] (Oxford University Press, 2005).

The banks' choice

This mechanism has generated impressive economic growth in both deficit and surplus countries; but it is inherently unstable. Large trade imbalances [7] generate larger increases in financial transactions and rising financial fragility, as rapidly increasing central-bank reserves (due to the US current-account deficit) provide the fuel for inflationary pressures and for mushrooming growth of the financial sector relative to other sectors. Banking crises, foreign-exchange crises, housing crises and the like become more likely (see Richard Duncan's book, The Dollar Crisis [8] [Wiley, 2005], and his "Blame the dollar standard", FinanceAsia, September 2007 [9]) [subscription only]).


More specifically, central banks, faced with rising reserves denominated mostly in dollars, have a choice of three types of dollar assets:


(a) the bonds of the US government, in the form of Treasury bonds


(b) the bonds of "quasi-government" agencies, or government-sponsored enterprises [10] (GSEs), like the mortgage lenders Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac


(c) asset-backed securities issued by the private sector.


The banks' preference is for government bonds, the safest. But the supply and therefore the price of Treasury bonds depend on the state of the US budget deficit. When it is in or near surplus the supply is low and the price relatively high - therefore the returns are relatively low; and so the central banks switch their purchases to (b) or (c).


The turbo-charger effect


In the late 1990s, with both the US current-account deficit and foreign central-bank reserves continuing to increase, the US budget went into surplus thanks to the internet bubble and fast overall growth. The supply of government (Treasury) bonds therefore fell. Foreign central banks switched their demand to the next safest US asset, quasi-government bonds, in particular those of the mortgage lenders. So Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac [11] enormously expanded their bond-issuance and mortgage-lending in the next several years, initiating the housing-market bubble.


But then the US budget went into deficit after the collapse of the stock-market bubble and the George W Bush administration's tax cuts [12], and the Treasury needed to sell more bonds. To cut a long story short, it engineered a halt to the issue of any more quasi-government bonds (to curb competition with government bonds), and foreign central-banks' demand switched back to government bonds.


By 2004 the property boom initiated earlier was generating rapid and broad-based economic growth in the US (enough [13] to get Bush re-elected). So tax revenues increased and the US budget again went into surplus. The supply of new Treasury bonds fell.


Foreign central banks, with still fast-rising dollar reserves meeting a smaller supply of US government and quasi-government bonds, therefore switched to the third category of US assets, so-called asset-backed securities [14] (ABSs). Between 2003 and 2004 the issuance of ABSs in the US more than doubled, and then almost doubled again in 2005. A large part of these ABSs was backed by mortgages - mortgages issued not so much by the quasi-government mortgage lenders as by private banks and other financial organisations.


To generate new demand, the latter developed new kinds of mortgages [15] aimed at people previously not able to obtain mortgages on conventional terms: the so-called "sub-prime" mortgages, or "liar" loans, or Ninja loans (no income, no job). The mortgagees were told that continuously rising house prices would allow them to "extract equity" from the rising value of the house and in this way meet the higher repayments when the repayment terms toughened in a year or two. The private banks developed techniques [16] of "securitising" the mortgages, techniques known by the impressive-sounding term "structured finance", by which combinations of highly risky mortgages could be packaged and sold - and given AAA ratings by the rating agencies on the pretext that the risk was widely dispersed (hence the ironic appellation, Ninja AAA loans).

This mechanism constituted a turbo-charger [17] on the US house market. House prices escalated, the bubble intensified.


It was not only foreign central banks which accumulated dollars and sought to buy US dollar assets; so too did commercial banks, insurance companies, pension funds and the like. And they were not only non-US investors; US investors were also seeking to buy the same "risk-free" assets.


Meanwhile, US consumption soared, spurred on by equity extraction from rising house values, and so therefore did the US trade deficit. The jump in US imports helped to fuel a global economic boom in 2004-06; to which China's fast growth [18], itself fuelled by exports to the US, contributed via improved terms of trade for commodity producers in developing countries. The world economy grew at its fastest rate in decades in 2004-06.


Globalisation was cheered [19] to the rooftops; the views of "anti-globalisation" activists were being confounded (so the argument went), as free-market capitalism was evidently working to bring widely disbursed economic growth and associated benefits, even in parts of Africa.


The cost of collapse


The bursting of the property bubble in the US in 2006 triggered a sequence in which, slowly, banking and financial operators became aware that the foundation of the debt pyramid was quicksand [21]. The US house buyer/consumer (below the top 20% of households) was increasingly insolvent, or nearly so. The large international banks, hoping for the best, waited until the summer of 2007 before they began to acknowledge that many of their complex debt instruments (ABSs) were non-performing [22]: the debts could not be repaid, yet the banks were counting them as revenue-yielding assets. But in August 2007 they jammed on the brakes and cut lending, including to each other - and in many other parts of the Atlantic economy (not just the US) as well.

The knock-on effect of the falls in house prices and the rise in repossessions in the US mean that all other mortgage markets are in trouble - including cars and credit-cards [23]. Unemployment is growing, consumption is stagnant.


The figure to watch is the ratio of total US debt to GDP [24]. The ratio of rising debt to GDP has fuelled US growth in the past several decades (it went from 240% in 1990 to 340% in 2006). If total debt/GDP suddenly flattens, the US will experience a recession. If US debt/GDP falls, the world will experience a recession, because its fall will go with a fall in US consumption, which accounts for at least 20% of world consumption. The crisis has already spread to housing markets and mortgage lenders in the US, Germany, France, Spain, and South Korea. It will soon affect China and Japan, which are the two biggest holders [25] by far of US national debt and stand to lose the most from a steep dollar devaluation. They are also large net exporters to the US, and will suffer from a fall in their US exports as the US contracts.


Meanwhile, oil has hit a record $84 a barrel, up from $24 in 2003; this generates a strong inflationary dynamic because of the effect on transport costs (equivalent to a general tariff increase). The price of uranium [26] has jumped more than ten times since 2000, from $3.18 per kilogram to $38.6 per kilogram in 2007. The existing 440 nuclear reactors in the world require 82 million kilograms of uranium per year; but mines supply only 45.5m (the balance comes from national stockpiles and decommissioned nuclear weapons). Production from existing mines is falling; yet another ninety nuclear plants [27] are either under construction or in planning. As though this was not enough, the price of wheat is at record levels and world wheat stocks at their lowest for decades; which adds to the other sources of inflationary pressure, in the form of higher food costs.


Saudi Arabia looks set to greatly reduce [28] the weight of dollars in its reserves, accelerating the fall of the dollar. Its action would probably trigger a stampede out of depreciating [29] dollar assets by other Gulf oil exporters (which currently have the fourth largest holdings of US national debt, after China, Japan and Britain).

The turmoil might even induce a shift in the neo-liberal consensus about the role of government in governing the market. Even the industrial and financial sectors might become more sympathetic to the idea of more limits on some kinds of markets (including for executive remuneration) - limits decided through a political process, in line with a social-democratic vision. After all, the Nordic countries achieve [30] astounding prosperity with a denser regulatory regime and substantially less inequality of income and wealth than in the more neo-liberally-oriented countries.


The Guardian's Larry Elliott [31] issues a useful caution here: "The sad fact is that only a deep recession is likely to generate enough national self-disgust at the destructive get-rich-quick value system oozing out of the City [of London] to create the political pressure for reform" (see "When money lenders cry for hand-outs [32]", Guardian, 10 September 2007).


The consequences of waiting for a deep recession will be greater than anything seen so far.



진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/11/01 12:28 2007/11/01 12:28

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Market Bondage (T. Palley)

View Comments

With Wall Street beset by a crisis of confidence and the mortgage-backed securities market seizing up, there is urgent need for an immediate emergency Federal Reserve interest rate cut. This sudden need has also revealed how today’s financial system places monetary policy in bondage to markets. That system has evolved over the past twenty-five years with the Fed’s approval, and the current crisis starkly reveals need for reform.

An emergency rate cut is needed to prevent the sub-prime mortgage meltdown from spiraling into a full-blown recession. By immediately lowering the base cost of credit, a rate cut can make existing mortgage securities more attractive to investors and also encourage continued flows of mortgage finance for the housing market.

Such continued financing is critical. In its absence mortgage availability will shrink and mortgage rates rise, thereby deepening the housing market slump. That is likely to trigger additional mortgage defaults and reductions in construction activity, thereby perhaps even causing a recession. In this event, the spiral of credit deterioration stands to deepen, jumping from the sub-prime mortgage market to the entire housing sector and the economy more broadly.

In response to this threat the Fed has already moved to inject significant temporary additional liquidity into money markets, effectively lending billions of dollars to banks to prevent their having to make further asset sales under current distressed conditions. Central banks in Europe, Japan, and elsewhere have done the same. However, because the costs of recession promise to be so large, the Fed must also move to cut rates.

As recently as ten days ago Fed policy was focused on containing inflation. Now, within the blink of an eye, the evaporation of confidence among Wall Street lenders has created conditions warranting an emergency rate cut to save the economy. This power of financial markets is rooted in a new business cycle that emerged in the 1980s and which has made the economy increasingly dependent on debt to fuel expansions. The creation of debt in turn relies on highly leveraged financial intermediaries that package and re-package loans while promising liquidity they are unable to deliver. As a result, the system has become fragile.

Increased financial fragility is one feature of the new system. A second and worse feature is that increased debt is part of a complex for shifting value from the real sector to the financial sector - a phenomenon known as “financialization”. This increases profits in the financial sector at the expense of the real economy. Meanwhile, the new structure also implicitly compels monetary policy to rescue the financial sector if it gets into trouble. This amounts to a policy stick-up whereby the Fed is forced to provide the get away car for fear that not doing so will result in even greater economic damage.

Today’s system places monetary policy in a double bind. In good times the Fed is forced to raise interest rates to maintain lender beliefs that inflation will remain low. Those beliefs ensure investors are willing to make the loans needed to fuel the system. However, the result is higher interest rates and curtailed expansions that hold down wages and employment, thereby limiting the share of productivity growth going to working families.

In bad times, such as we are now experiencing, the Fed is obliged to come to the rescue of lenders for fear that if they stop lending the economy will tank. Moreover, this fear deepens the greater the level and burden of debts. Worse yet, such intervention creates a problem known as “moral hazard” that can aggravate the need for rescues. Having the Fed intervene to prevent financial meltdowns tacitly puts a floor under financial markets. That floor acts as a form of insurance for investors and speculators, who knowing that they are protected against large losses then channel more funds into even higher risk investments and loans.

The Fed has actively promoted the new system through deregulation. Its claim has been the risks of the financial system imploding are less because risk is spread. That claim is now being shown to be false.

For two decades working families have felt the effects of the policy head-lock imposed by financial market demands for ultra-low inflation. Now, financial markets are exercising their other demand for interest rate cuts to preserve asset values in order to prevent recession.

 

The threat posed by the current crisis is such that the Fed should meet this demand. That means immediately cutting rates and continuing to judiciously provide emergency liquidity. However, once the storm passes Congress and the Fed must address the systemic problems and policy distortions that have been exposed by the current crisis.

Copyright Thomas I. Palley

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/08/22 06:30 2007/08/22 06:30

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Money markets hit reverse (FT)

View Comments

Money markets hit reverse on hopes for rate cut

By Krishna Guha in Washington and Saskia Scholtes n New York

Published: August 21 2007 15:39 | Last updated: August 21 2007 21:09

Money markets on Tuesday staged a dramatic reversal of Monday’s flight to safety, after an influential US senator fuelled expectations that the US Federal Reserve would soon cut interest rates.

Christopher Dodd, the chairman of the Senate banking committee, told reporters after a meeting with Ben Bernanke, the Fed chairman, and Hank Paulson, US Treasury secretary, that Mr Bernanke had told him he would use “all the tools” at his disposal to contain market turmoil and prevent it from damaging the economy.

The revelation helped turn around investor sentiment after an earlier warning by Mr Paulson that there was no quick solution to the problems in credit markets.

Mr Dodd said Mr Bernanke also indicated that he was not satisfied with the market’s response to the Fed’s decision on Friday to make direct loans available to banks on attractive terms through its discount window.

The meeting of the three men on Capitol Hill highlights the increasing political pressure on the Fed.

Fed insiders played down the significance of Mr Dodd’s remarks, indicating that there was no change in policy since Friday, when it put out a statement saying it was “prepared to act as needed to mitigate the adverse effects on the economy arising from the disruptions in financial markets”.

The Fed was not expecting market conditions to improve dramatically following Friday’s move, so it will not be too disheartened by the mixed developments since then.

Nonetheless, Mr Dodd’s comments helped sustain a pull-back in the short-term government debt market, where investors had pushed yields down to remarkable lows amid a desperate scramble for safe government paper.

The yield on the one-month Treasury bill showed the sharpest move, rising by 87 basis points to 2.98 per cent by late afternoon in New York, while the three-month bill yield was 43bp higher on the day at 3.61 per cent. Investors had initially poured into short-term government debt yesterday, extending a flight to quality as they shunned the commercial paper market.

The move had pushed yields in the market for Treasury bills around 30 basis points lower, driving the yield on one-month bills below 2 per cent and the three-month bill yield below 3 per cent. The flight to safety had also extended to the two-year Treasury note, which saw its yield fall below the psychologically significant level of 4 per cent yesterday.

In a further sign of investor risk aversion, the pricing differential between higher and lower-rated commercial paper issued by non-financial companies ex­panded to the widest levels since the aftermath of the terrorist attacks on September 11 2001.

“Credit is being repriced, reassessed across our capital markets,” Mr Paulson told CNBC television. “As the Fed addresses liquidity this makes it possible, this makes it easier, for the market to focus on risk and pricing risk. This will play out over time.”

Conditions in equity markets remained tense as convulsions swept through the money and credit markets. By midday in New York, the S&P 500 index was up 0.4 per cent at 1,451.59 while in Europe, leading shares ended the day flat after a late rally.

European shares were weighed down by fresh concerns about the exposure of the German banking sector to turmoil in the US subprime mortgage market.

Underlining the severity of US subprime woes on German banks following the near-collapse of lender IKB this month, Alexander Stuhlmann, chief executive of lender WestLB, said the sector was in a “not uncritical situation” overall.

But shares in Asia continued to rally from last week’s rout. The Morgan Stanley Capital International Asia-Pacific index was up 1.2 per cent in the early evening in Tokyo. This took its rise over the past two days to 5.3 per cent.

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/08/22 06:24 2007/08/22 06:24

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

FT Bridging poverty gap should be IMF priority

View Comments

Bridging poverty gap should be IMF priority

By Chrystia Freeland and Edward Luce in Washington

Published: July 27 2007 23:24 | Last updated: July 27 2007 23:24

Bridging the gap between rich and poor countries should be as high a priority for the International Monetary Fund as helping to solve the world’s financial imbalances, Dominique Strauss Kahn, the probable next managing director of the IMF told the Financial Times.

The former French finance minister, who is on a world tour to win support for his candidacy to head the IMF, said that “going south of the Equator” would matter just as much as going “east to the Pacific” – a reference to deep concerns about the growing trade gap between China and the developed world. Mr Strauss Kahn will fly to Mozambique on Sunday to meet African finance ministers and then over the following two weeks to Mexico, Argentina, South Africa, Brazil, Saudi Arabia, Egypt, China, South Korea, Japan, India and Russia in what he freely described as a “campaign” among the largest developing countries to get the job.

The position opened up unexpectedly last month following the resignation of Rodrigo de Rato, the former Spanish finance minister, for personal reasons.

Asked whether Europe should continue to maintain its stranglehold on the top IMF job as the US does with the World Bank, Mr Strauss Kahn said he supported an open process and would welcome candidates from other parts of the world if they threw their hats into the ring before the closing date at the end of August.

“It is entirely legitimate for any country that is a member of the IMF to promote one of their nationals as a candidate,” he told the FT in his first interview since being proposed for the job.

“But of course that does not mean that a European cannot also be a candidate,” he added.

On Friday the Bush administration formally endorsed Mr Strauss Kahn’s candidacy following his meeting with Hank Paulson, the US treasury secretary.

Mr Strauss Kahn on Friday also met Bob Zoellick, the new president of the World Bank, who moved into the job following the unexpected resignation of Paul Wolfowitz last month.

He said his top priorities would be to address both financial and equity imbalances in the world economy and to improve the governance structure and quota system of the IMF to better reflect the growing weight of developing countries in the world economy.

He said he believed the IMF could “adapt” to make itself more relevant to the challenges of globalisation.

“I believe strongly in multilateralism,” he said.

“I think that at this time of globalisation we need more multilaleralism – not less,” adding that he believed the US had recently become “more committed to “multilateralism”.

He said that the “integration” of poor countries into the global economy would be a top priority if he got the job.

 

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/07/29 14:04 2007/07/29 14:04

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

FT Brazil claims WTO cotton victory

View Comments

Brazil claims WTO cotton victory

By John Rumsey in São Paulo, Frances Williams in Geneva and Eoin Callan in Washington

Published: July 27 2007 23:19 | Last updated: July 27 2007 23:19

Brazil on Friday claimed victory in its latest assault on US cotton subsidies at the World Trade Organisation, underscoring warnings by the Bush administration that the subsidy-laden farm bill under consideration by Congress risks triggering a wave of trade disputes.

Brazil said a confidential interim ruling by a WTO panel had gone in its favour.

The panel, due to issue its final decision in September, was set up last year to judge whether the US had fully complied with a 2005 WTO appeal verdict condemning several subsidy programmes for cotton farmers.

In response to that verdict, the US scrapped or amended programmes considered to be illegal export subsidies. However, Brazil says this left untouched some of the most trade-distorting subsidies, such as marketing loans and counter-cyclical payments that compensate farmers for low prices.

The US House of Representatives was set to vote late on Friday on a controversial $256bn, five-year farm bill that eliminates subsidies for farmers with more than $1m in adjusted gross income but continues to give generous subsidies in key areas including corn, cotton, soya beans and rice.

The bill was approved by the House agricultural committee on July 19.

The Bush administration has threatened to veto the legislation, saying it leaves the US vulnerable to WTO challenges similar to the case brought by Brazil over support for cotton farmers.

Pedro Camargo Neto, ex-secretary of production and trade at the Brazilian Ministry of Agriculture, dismissed the likelihood of Brazil bringing further cases, such as against soy, sugar and rice, where it would be more difficult to prove damages.

The Brazil ruling should embolden other countries, such as Mexico and Uruguay, to seek redress over rice subsidies.

A US trade official confirmed on Friday that the WTO panel had found that the changes made by the US “were insufficient to bring the challenged measures into conformity with US WTO obligations . . . we are very disappointed with these results”.

Brazil and its allies have pressed for big reductions in US and European Union farm support in the Doha global trade round.

The latest draft text by the chair of the Doha round’s agricultural negotiations calls specifically for deeper and faster-than-average cuts in cotton subsidies in developed countries.

Critics say such subsidies hurt not only Brazil but also millions of poor West African cotton farmers.

Still, with a successful conclusion to the round uncertain, the WTO’s dispute mechanism is increasingly seen as an alternative if ponderous route to the same end.

 

In 2005, Brazil, Thailand and Australia won another landmark case against EU sugar subsidies and this year Canada and Brazil have each filed new complaints alleging US overspending on trade-distorting farm aid.

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/07/29 14:02 2007/07/29 14:02

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Jagdish Bhagwati - US Senate Finance Committee Testimony

View Comments

Senate Finance Committee Testimony on US TRADE POLICY: THE CHINA QUESTON Jagdish Bhagwati University Professor, Economics and Law

 

Let me begin by saying how honored I am to have been invited to appear before your Committee, Senator Baucus. I have long been familiar with the leadership you have provided on trade issues in the Senate over many years, enabling the United States to be the major player in the liberalization of world trade that has brought so many indisputable benefits to us and to many nations around the world.

You have asked me to address the question of China and what it implies for US trade policy. China, of course, has long been an important source of controversy for US trade policymakers. The debates over whether to grant it MFN status were followed by whether, and on what conditions, it should be admitted to the WTO (World Trade Organization). I recall how USTR Charlene Barshefsky arrived from Beijing with an agreement on the terms of Chinese entry into the

WTO just in time in Seattle in November 1999 for the WTO meeting which blew up in the face of President Clinton and the rest of us, postponing by two years to 2001 the start of the Doha Round of multilateral trade negotiations.

Many were certain that the focus on China had detracted from the US preparations and preparedness over the Seattle meeting, illustrating tangentially how multilateral trade liberalization is often handicapped, not advanced, by distractions over bilateral and plurilateral (i.e. with members exceeding two but less than all nations) trade negotiations.

Today, the issue of China is even more prominently at the center of a major debate over US trade policy. But the stakes in this debate are higher as the China question now is part of a substantive debate, especially after the last election, over the question whether further freeing of trade or a retreat (however slow) into de facto protectionism makes sense for the United States. More precisely, the China question is one of two issues today that must be addressed regarding our trade policy. So, let me say a few words about the other issue, and then turn more bodily to the China question which you are addressing today.

I: Inclusion of Labor and (Domestic) Environmental Standards in Trade Treaties: Case of “Export Protectionism”

The first relates to the fact that the New Democrats have been elected, with a Democratic majority, in the last Congressional election with promises to require labor and (domestic) environmental standards as central features of trade treaties. While there are groups that want to spread higher standards because of altruism and sympathy, the motivation that prompts the demands for inclusion of labour standards elsewhere as preconditions for trade liberalization by the United States --- these demands come from AFL-CIO and the new Democrats are reflecting for political convenience these demands while some share the AFL-CIO viewpoints independently of voting considerations, for sure --- is quite simply self-interest and fear.

The demands that labor and environmental standards, for example, must be demanded from others with low standards because otherwise free trade would be “unfair” have long been exposed as unpersuasive. Let me state here just a few of the counter-arguments against such demands: systematic analysis of the different rationales proposed for them is available in many other places and needs to be consulted for a fuller understanding of the protectionist dangers we currently

face.

First, if these demands take the common form that others must have similar “burdens” as our producers do, it is easy to see that standards, theirs and ours, are generally speaking different for perfectly legitimate reasons and that our objecting to others’ standards is as right or wrong as their objecting to ours.

Would we then let others exclude our exports simply because our standards are lower than those of Europe, even Canada’s, in many areas? In case one doubts that US standards are lower, just think of the obvious examples. Almost alone in the world, we allow capital punishment, including the capital punishment of juveniles. Or take the several international reports on the state of our prisons, and our widespread use of prison labour to produce goods for sale by firms who are not required to pay minimum wage payments and offer labour protections. Then again, on the right to unionize, the Human Rights Watch (with whom I work on 1 I, among many others, have written extensively on why the attempts to include labor and domestic environmental standards in trade treaties are misguided. Especially, exactly ten years ago, I and the late Professor Robert Hudec produced two substantial volumes on the subject; see Bhagwati and Hudec (eds), Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade?, MIT Press: Cambridge, Mass., 1996. I have also written extensively on the subject in the American Journal of International Law, in my Testimony to this Committee on the FTA with Jordan, and in many op ed articles in The Financial Times etc. I have not seen any persuasive response to my criticisms. My sense is that the AFL-CIO is no longer interested in arguments (where they cannot win) and have decided to go exclusively to the political route. Given their substantial resources, evidently, it is a smart strategy for them to substitute financial for human capital!

 

the Academic Advisory Committee on Asia) has produced a detailed analysis which concludes that this right is effectively denied to “millions” in the US, largely (but not exclusively) because the right to strike has been crippled by the Taft-Hartley provisions. Indeed, many abroad find it very hard to believe that, with little more than 10% of our labor force unionized, and with wide appreciation of the legislated difficulties faced by unions in organizing labor, we can claim that we have the higher moral ground in these matters. At a time when the Bush administration’s unilateralism has provoked serious anti- Americanism, the self-righteous tone of our labor and environmental lobbies and the dissonance between our postures and our own practice are also not likely to make the United States any more likeable to the world.

Second, and equally important, our attempts at imposing such standards on the developing countries will not succeed with the larger and economically more important developing countries such as India and Brazil. These countries are fully democratic; they are neither more dictatorships nor violators of human rights than we are. In fact, India is a splendid democracy which has managed to manage multi-religiosity, multi-ethnicity and diversity within a democratic framework. Its unions are also free; and its environmental movement is strong. As for Brazil, President Lula has risen from the ranks of the trade union movement and has better credentials as a trade unionist than even John Sweeney! Yet, both India and Brazil strongly reject the inclusion of labor and environmental standards in trade treaties. In fact, India just recently told the EU that they could not have an FTA with it unless if non-trade issues were mixed up with it, causing EU to go back to the bargaining table; and the same can be confidently expected to be the case with the US. It is also noteworthy that no trade treaty purely among developing countries has these extraneous non-trade issues within it: it is a characteristic of bilateral trade treaties that hegemonic powers, with their lobbies, impose on lesser countries in one-on-one, unevenly-matched bargains. If the new Democrats want to go down this route, they face the prospect of confining their trade liberalization to weak, ineffectual nations which will roll over when faced with such demands.

Some liberalization indeed!

Third, key political leaders in the US, until recently, were cognizant of the fact that it was more efficient to pursue labor agendas in the ILO and trade issues in the WTO and in other trade treaties and institutions. Senator Patrick Daniel Moynihan frequently wrote to me agreeing with this position, including sending me for my files a memo to this effect, based on an op ed of mine, signed by POUTS as “seen”.

It has become fashionable for some commentators such as the political science Professor Mac Destler and the journalist Mr. Bruce Stokes to say that the US has become less protectionist in recent years. This is seriously wrong. Yes, we probably have less sectoral, import protection. But the protectionism we now face is across-the-board, export protectionism. The attempts at raising labor and domestic environmental standards as preconditions for trade liberalization are transparent attempts by a terrified labor movement, and sympathetic media personalities like Lou Dobbs, to raise the cost of production of rivals in the poor countries so that the force of competition is moderated. Imagine a beast charging at you: you can either catch it by the horn (i.e. conventional import protectionism) or reach behind it, catch it by the tail and break the charge (i.e. export protectionism). The forced raising of standards in the poor countries desirous of trading with us is “export protectionism”: It is insidious because it is not transparent to the general public as such and partly because it can be successfully disguised as altruism and empathy for the people in the poor countries. It is also invidious because it is not confined to specific sectors but cuts across many sectors, indeed wherever the imposition of such standards by de facto exercise of political power manages to raise the cost of production of rival firms abroad.

It is a dangerous protectionist beast that the new Democrats, and several compliant Republicans who would rather advance business deals than stand for any principles, are therefore turning loose on the trade arena. But the other major threat comes form China today. Part of it is from China’s low standards on human, and hence labor, rights and so what I have argued above holds. Since such diametrically opposed recommendations are not uncommon in macroeconomics, and even the proponents of Chinese Renminbi revaluation divide into many camps on the extent of the desirable revaluation.

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/07/13 13:49 2007/07/13 13:49

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

CALLS FOR IMF LEADERSHIP REFORMS

View Comments

BACK TO MAIN  |  ONLINE BOOKSTORE  |  HOW TO ORDER

TWN Info Service on Finance and Development (Jul07/02)

4 July 2007


CALLS FOR IMF LEADERSHIP REFORMS AFTER DE RATO RESIGNATION

Calls for an end to the archaic leadership selection process at the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have been renewed after the surprise mid-term resignation of its managing director Rodrigo de Rato for “personal reasons” last Thursday. Following de Rato’s announcement that he is to step down in October after the Bank and Fund annual meetings, civil society groups revived their calls to end the 63-year-old “gentlemen’s agreement” at the Bretton Woods institutions which gives European governments the prerogative to select the IMF chief while the United States government appoints the president of the World Bank.

De Rato’s departure at this point in time means that his successor will inherit an institution in crisis and one that is undergoing an ambitious but controversial and deeply divisive programme of policy and operational reform.

Below is a report on the reactions to de Rato’s resignation published in SUNS # 6283 Monday 2 July 2007.

With best wishes
Martin Khor, TWN

Calls for IMF Leadership Reforms after de Rato Resignation

By Celine Tan

Calls for an end to the archaic leadership selection process at the International Monetary Fund (IMF) have been renewed after the surprise mid-term resignation of its managing director Rodrigo de Rato for “personal reasons” last Thursday.

Following de Rato’s announcement that he is to step down in October after the Bank and Fund annual meetings, civil society groups revived their calls to end the 63-year-old “gentlemen’s agreement” at the Bretton Woods institutions which gives European governments the prerogative to select the IMF chief while the United States government appoints the president of the World Bank.

In a press statement, a coalition of UK-based NGOs, including leading charities such as Oxfam, ActionAid and Christian Aid, have called upon the UK government and other European countries to seize the opportunity to implement a transparent and merit-based appointment system at the Fund, a chance that was missed in the recent World Bank leadership changeover.

De Rato’s resignation also placed both the Bretton Woods institutions in leadership transition, as its sister institution, the World Bank, sees Robert Zoellick take over its helm from current embattled president Paul Wolfowitz this weekend.

The Bretton Woods Project (BWP), a Bank and Fund watchdog, said that European countries have been given a second chance at reforming the governance of the international financial institutions following the recent failure to implement such reforms at the Bank.

According to BWP’s policy and advocacy officer, Peter Chowla, European governments had “missed a historic opportunity” with the nominations for Wolfowitz’s successor but “they can atone by ensuring that the next IMF managing director is selected through an open, transparent and inclusive process, where selection is based on merit, not nationality, and where the views of all members have equal weight”.

The statement added that “with three months before de Rato’s departure, there is plenty of time to establish and implement a selection process that might be seen as appropriate to such a senior appointment at the national level”.

This call will no doubt be reiterated by developing-country governments for whom the current governance structure of the Bretton Woods institutions disadvantages through their weighted voting system.

The Financial Times cites a diplomat from the Group of 20 (a grouping comprised of the G7, the EU and 11 emerging economies) as saying that the de Rato resignation “will give fresh momentum to the push for reform of the selection process”.

According to the report, Brazil, South Africa and Australia had led demands for the reform of the World Bank selection process after Wolfowitz’s resignation in May but were rebuffed by the US. The White House nominated Zoellick, former deputy secretary of state and US trade representative, to the post and he was appointed unopposed after just 17 days of nominations.

De Rato himself had called for a reform of the Fund’s leadership selection process. In his report on the institution’s Medium-Term Strategy to the Executive Board in April this year, de Rato said that “a transparent procedure for the selection of the Managing Director should be formally approved”.

He had said that as the management has an important role “in maintaining the integrity, credibility and independence of the institution”, its membership needed “to respond to the calls for a transparent process by adopting and publishing guidelines on the selection of the Managing Director”.

The leadership appointment is one component of a larger basket of governance reforms called for by developing countries and civil society at the IMF, including most notably the weighted voting structure which results in industrialized countries holding 71% of the voting power at the institution (the US wields almost 17% of the votes and has effective veto power), while developing countries have less than a third share.

De Rato is currently overseeing efforts at reforming the voice and representation system at the institution which includes a two-stage process to overhaul the outdated quota system used to determine members’ financial subscriptions to the Fund, access to Fund resources and their voting power within the institution.

However, so far, there has been little agreement on what would constitute the basis of the new formula with many developing countries calling for a formula measured at purchasing power parity (PPP) levels while industrialized countries want to introduce openness, including openness to trade, as a factor.

De Rato’s departure at this point in time means that his successor will inherit an institution in crisis and one that is undergoing an ambitious but controversial and deeply divisive programme of policy and operational reform.

The outgoing IMF chief is also supervising an institutional work programme which includes implementation of the new bilateral surveillance framework approved by the Executive Board two weeks ago but opposed by China, as well as plans to revamp the Fund’s revenue model to secure the institution’s financial future in the wake of declining inflows.

Some observers have already questioned the viability of these reform packages in the wake of de Rato’s announcement, although de Rato had pledged his determination to “make further progress on all aspects of the medium-term strategy in the coming months, especially on quotas and voice but also Fund income, crisis prevention, and on collaboration with the World Bank in low-income countries”.

However, many developing countries have already expressed disappointment in the manner in which some of the reforms have been pushed through by the controlling membership of the institution. Many view the reforms as tokenistic at best and disingenuous at worst.

Chinese officials and analysts have already criticized the recent adoption of the aforementioned surveillance decision as bilateralism cloaked in a veneer of multilateralism with the reforms motivated by US efforts to pressure for faster appreciation of the renminbi (see separate article).

The selection process of the new IMF managing director will thus take place amidst uncertainty about the role of the institution in the current international financial architecture and its significance as a multilateral financial organisation.

The continuance of the present outmoded practice of leadership selection based on a postwar, trans-Atlantic power-sharing arrangement will undoubtedly raise questions about the authenticity of the governance reform process underway at the Fund.

De Rato’s own appointment in 2004 was heavily criticised, with his selection process described by the Bretton Woods Project as a “one-horse race” with “squabbling jockeys”, as European countries bickered over their choice of candidate to put forward to the institution.

At the time, NGOs had condemned the horse-trading that led to De Rato’s selection and the secrecy that surrounded the decision to appoint him over the Egyptian nominee, Mohamed El-Erian, who lost in an apparent “secret straw vote”.

According to the Bretton Woods Project and the Italian-based Campaign to Reform the World Bank (CRBM), “backroom political deals ensured Rato’s election, making a mockery of the vote. Due to the lack of transparency of board proceedings, we can’t even know how much support El-Erian received in the straw vote”.

This time round, NGOs called for a halt to this non-transparent process. Romily Greenhill from ActionAid commented: “We hope that European governments will have the strength to finally end the backroom deal with the US that has perpetuated the outdated carve-up of the leadership at the IMF and World Bank”.

De Rato, a former Spanish finance minister, is the ninth managing director of the IMF and served only two and half years of his tenure. He cited “family circumstances and responsibilities, particularly with regard to the education of my children” for relinquishing his post.

 


진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/07/13 06:02 2007/07/13 06:02

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

TPA Expires

View Comments

TWN Info Service on WTO and Trade Issues (July 07/03)

6 July 2007

 

The United States government's ability to negotiate trade deals took many knocks last weekend when its President's "fast track authority" expired with no hope for a quick renewal.

This throws into question whether it is possible for partners of the US to negotiate trade deals with confidence that any agreement (whether bilateral trade agreements or a WTO Doha agreement) that is concluded will be honoured by the US.

First, fast track authority expired on midnight of 30 June. Second, the Democrat's Congressional leaders issued a statement indicating they will not renew the fast track anytime soon. Third, the Democrats also announced that they would not approve two bilateral FTAs the US administration has already concluded, under the old fast track authority, with South Korea and Colombia. Below is a report on the fast track situation.

Best wishes
Martin Khor
TWN

US Fast track expires with no hope of fast renewal

By Martin Khor (TWN), Geneva, 2 July 2007

The United States government's ability to negotiate trade deals took many knocks last weekend when its President's "fast track authority" expired with no hope for a quick renewal.

This throws into question whether it is possible for partners of the US to negotiate trade deals with confidence that any agreement (whether bilateral trade agreements or a WTO Doha agreement) that is concluded will be honoured by the US.

First, the President's fast track authority expired on midnight of 30 June. This means that Bush no longer has the power to negotiate trade deals in the knowledge that there is a reasonable chance for the deals to be adopted by the US Congress.

Second, the leaders of the Democrats that control the Congress and Senate have dashed the Bush administration's hopes that a new fast track authority will be given to the President anytime soon.

Third, the Democrats have also announced that they would not approve two bilateral free trade agreements that the US administration has already concluded, under the old fast track authority, with South Korea and Colombia.

These three blows to the President's trade policy authority means that the wind will be taken out of current negotiations that the US is conducting, or hoping to conduct, on bilateral FTAs with countries including Malaysia, Indonesia, Vietnam and Thailand.

There will also be a negative effect on the World Trade Organisation's Doha negotiations because other WTO members would now be uncertain whether any positions put forward by or agreed to by the US can be sustained once the agreement goes up before the Congress.

The so-called "fast track authority" is provided to a US President under the Trade Promotion Authority (TPA) Act. It allows the government to negotiate and conclude trade agreements that Congress must approve or reject as a whole, without making any changes.

This is considered important for negotiating partners of the US to have confidence that what has been agreed on will be honoured by the US, as otherwise, the Congress could make several significant changes to the agreement.

For weeks before the TPA expired on 1 July, Bush and the US Trade Representative Susan Schwab campaigned with the US Congress to get the fast track authority "renewed."

This would have required a new TPA to be adopted by Congress. With the Democrats having swept into power in both Houses last year on the back of promises to review the country's trade policy (as many Americans blame trade for job losses and insecurity), it was always unlikely that they would give Bush a new TPA.

In any case, the Democrats would want to put in many new provisions and conditions in any new TPA to be established, and this would take time to craft.

Moreover, the Democrats are not in a mood to give further power to Bush, a President with who they disagree passionately on many issues.

The last time a fast track authority lapsed was in 1994, when Bill Clinton was President, and it took eight years before a new TPA was established.

Last Friday, the Democrat House Speaker Nancy Pelosi and other Democrat Congress leaders issued a statement saying that "our legislative priorities do not include the renewal of fast track authority. Before that debate can even begin, we must expand the benefits of globalization to all Americans, including taking the actions outlined above."

The actions mentioned include addressing the increased economic insecurity faced by American families arising from trade, and new legislation that the Democrats are planning to "address the growing imbalance in trade with China, strengthen overall enforcement of US trade agreements and US trade laws, as well as overhaul and improve support to ensure that American workers and firms remain the most competitive in the world."

Needless to say, it will take quite some time for such new legislation to be debated within the Democrat circle itself, and to be introduced and debated in Congress, and thus any new TPA will have to wait in line for months or years.

The Democrat leaders also announced that they would approve bilateral FTAs that the US has signed with Peru and Panama, but would reject FTAs with Colombia and South Korea.

The Peru and Panama agreements had been signed months ago. The Democrats then negotiated with the US administration to inject new provisions in seven areas in the FTAs with these two countries.

The issues include labour standards, environment and global warming, patents and access to medicines, government procurement, port security, and investment.

For Congress to approve the deals, the two countries have to agree to include the new language, even after they had already signed their FTAs with the US. This exercise shows that even after an FTA is concluded, it can be re-opened for the US to put in new demands.

South Korea also signed an amended FTA with the US last Saturday. However, the chances of it being approved by Congress are now reduced, because the Democrat leaders said that they cannot support the pact as currently negotiated. The agreement may have to undergo yet another round of amendments, if it is to survive a Congress vote.

The reason given in the Democrats' statement is that the FTA does not address non-tariff barriers blocking access of US manufactured products in South Korea's market. The Democrats mentioned the automotive sector where last year South Korea exported more than 700,000 cars into the US, while the US exported fewer than 5,000.

The Democrats also rejected the FTA with Colombia because of the violence against trade union members, "the impunity, the lack of investigations and prosecutions, and the role of the paramilitary." 

 


 

Fast track expires with no hope of fast renewal

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/07/13 06:00 2007/07/13 06:00

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Krugman on Trade and Inequality

View Comments

Trade and inequality, revisited
Paul Krugman 15 June 2007

It’s no longer safe to assert that trade’s impact on the income distribution in wealthy countries is fairly minor. There’s a good case that it is big, and getting bigger. I’m not endorsing protectionism, but free-traders need
better answers to the anxieties of globalisation’s losers.

During the 1980s and 1990s, there was considerable concern about the possible role of globalisation in contributing to rising income inequality, especially in the United States. This concern was based on standard economic theory: since the 1941 Stolper-Samuelson paper, we’ve known that growing trade can have large effects on income distribution, and can easily leave broad groups, such as less-skilled workers, worse off.

After economists looked hard at the numbers, however, the consensus was that the effect of trade on inequality was probably modest. Recently, Ben Bernanke cited these results – but he recognised a problem: “Unfortunately, much of the available empirical research on the influence of trade on earnings inequality dates from the 1980s and 1990s and thus does not address later developments. Whether studies of the more recent period will reveal effects of trade on the distribution of earnings that differ from those observed earlier is to some degree an open question.”

But the question isn’t really that open. It’s clear that applying the same models to current data that, for example, led William Cline of the Peterson Institute to conclude in 1997 that trade was responsible for a 6% widening in the college-high school gap would lead to a much larger estimate today.
Furthermore, some of the considerations that once seemed to set limits on the possible inequality-promoting effects of trade now seem much less constraining.

There are really two key points here: the rise of China, and the growing fragmentation of production.

First, thanks to the rise of China, OECD imports of manufactured goods from developing countries have continued to rise rapidly since the early 1990s. Cline’s estimate of income distribution effects was based on data from 1993, when US imports of manufactures from developing countries were approximately
2% of GDP; now that number is close to 5%, and rising rapidly.

At the same time, the rise of China has prevented, for the time being, a development that I and others expected to mitigate the effects of trade on income distribution: up-skilling by the developing country exporters. “As newly industrializing countries grow,” I wrote in 1995, “their comparative
advantage may shift away from products of very low skill intensity.” And that’s exactly what happened – for the countries that were the major exporters of manufactured goods to the OECD then. As John Romalis has shown, the exports of the original group of Asian newly-industrialising economies have shifted dramatically away from labour-intensive toward skill-intensive products.

But along has come China, which is far more labour-abundant now than the NIEs were then. A simple indicator is relative wage rates: in 1990, according to the US Bureau of Labor Statistics, the original four Asian NIEs had hourly compensation costs that were 25% of the US level. Now the BLS estimates that China’s labour costs are only 3% of US levels.

In 1995 I also believed that the effects of trade on inequality would eventually hit a limit, because at a certain point advanced economies would run out of labour-intensive industries to lose – more formally, that we’d
reach a point of complete specialisation, beyond which further growth in trade would have no further effects on wages. What has happened instead is that the limit keeps being pushed out, as trade creates “new”
labour-intensive industries through the fragmentation of production.

For example, the manufacture of microprocessors for personal computers is clearly a highly sensitive, skill-intensive process. Intel’s microprocessor production, however, now takes place in two stages: the “fabs,” which print the circuits on disks of silicon, are all located in high-wage advanced countries, but the assembly and testing, in which those disks are cut into individual chips and tested to be sure that they work, is conducted in China, Malaysia, and the Philippines.

Outsourcing of services, in both directions, adds to the possibilities of unequalising trade. The skill-intensive pieces of production processes that mainly take place in the third world are often now located in the OECD – for example, Lenovo, the Chinese computer company, has its executive headquarters in North Carolina.

What all this comes down to is that it’s no longer safe to assert, as we could a dozen years ago, that the effects of trade on income distribution in wealthy countries are fairly minor. There’s now a good case that they are quite big, and getting bigger.

This doesn’t mean that I’m endorsing protectionism. It does mean that free-traders need better answers to the anxieties of those who are likely to end up on the losing side from globalisation.

http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/261
진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크
2007/06/19 12:48 2007/06/19 12:48

댓글0 Comments (+add yours?)

트랙백0 Tracbacks (+view to the desc.)

Newer Entries Older Entries