사이드바 영역으로 건너뛰기

쇠퇴하는 자본주의, 노동자계급의 길은 무엇인가?

  • 분류
    잡기장
  • 등록일
    2011/11/10 10:52
  • 수정일
    2011/11/10 10:52
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

쇠퇴하는 자본주의, 노동자계급의 길은 무엇인가?

                                                                      이형로

 

 

 

올해 여름 극단적으로 첨예화된 경제위기는 자본주의 체제가 그 한계에 도달했음을 분명하게 보여주었다. ‘금융위기’라고 불리는 현 위기의 본질적 성격은 자본주의 체제의 위기이다. 왜 체제 위기인가? 산업순환 위기(주기적 과잉생산 공황)를 넘어 역사적으로 1973년 이래 계속되어 온 구조적인 과잉축적 모순이 더 이상 봉합되지 못하여 마침내 폭발한 위기이기 때문이다.

 

 

1. 현 위기는 자본주의의 역사적 · 구조적 위기

 

최근 30여 년 동안만 보더라도 7년~10년에 한 번 씩 터져 나오는 순환적 공황들이 3-4 차례 있었지만, 자본가계급이 대대적인 경기부양과 거품경제를 일으켜 한 두 해만에 공황에서 벗어날 수 있었다. 그러나 2007년 하반기부터 시작한 현재의 공황은 “1930년대 세계대공황 이래 최대의 공황”, 또는 “제2차 세계대전 이래 최악의 경제위기”라고 저들도 이야기하는 것처럼 천문학적인 구제 금융과 경기부양책(두 차례에 걸친 양적완화)으로도 틀어막지 못한 채 지금까지 4년째 계속되고 있고, 나아가 심화되고 있다. (2009년 하반기에서2010년 중반 동안 일시적으로 회복의 기미들이 미약하게 나타났었는데, 이것이 자본가들로 하여금 ‘세계경제 위기는 끝났다’라고 잠시 착각하도록 만들었다.) 

 

정확히 말해서 현 위기는 순환적 위기에 자본주의 체제의 역사적인 위기가 중첩된 것이다. ‘역사적’이라 함은 7~10년의 산업적 주기(‘경기변동’ 주기)보다 훨씬 더 긴 기간을 통해 역사적으로(자본축적의 경제적 추세에 영향을 미치는 계급투쟁, 제국주의 국제관계 등의 정치 · 사회적 추세들을 포함한 구체 역사적 조건들을 매개하여) 누적되어 온 구조적 성격의 위기라는 뜻이다.

 

1973년부터 1982년까지의 대위기 동안 주식, 부동산 등의 자산 가치 폭락, 기업도산, 실업급증 등 과잉자본 파괴 과정이 진행되었지만, 제2차 세계대전만큼 철저한 청산이 이루어지지 못했고, 따라서 이윤율도 충분히 회복되지 못했다. 이 두 번째 대위기는 첫 번째 대위기에 비해 과잉자본 파괴 면에서 훨씬 덜 폭력적인 공황이었다고 할 수 있다. 이 시기가 1930년대와 같은 계급투쟁 격화와 파시즘 · 세계대전 같은 양상으로 전개되지 않았던 것도 이와 관련이 있다.

 

이와 같이 과잉축적 자본을 제대로 해소하지 못한 상태에서 1980년대에 대처리즘과 레이거노믹스로 상징되는 신자유주의 공세가 시작되었고, 1990년대에 와서는 동구권과 중국이 세계자본주의 체제로 통합되면서 미국 주도의 본격적인 세계화(또는 신자유주의 세계화) 국면에 들어갔다. 이 1980년대 초부터 2007년까지 약 30년간의 이른바 신자유주의 세계화 시기의 성격은 노동자계급에 대한 착취 강화와 금융투기 거품을 통해 이윤율 하락 및 과잉축적 위기(1973년-82년의 공황으로 충분히 해소되지 못한 과잉축적 위기)를 돌파하려고 하다가 오히려 그 위기를 누적적으로 가중시킨 시기라고 할 수 있다. 이렇게 누적되고 가중된 구조적 과잉축적 위기가 이번 2007년-2008년에 폭발적으로 터져 나온 것이다.

 

 

2. 해결할 수 없는 자본주의의 본질적 위기

 

현재의 위기는 단순히 팽창된 금융자본의 투기와 다양한 경제주체, 즉 정부, 가계 그리고 기업의 부채 미상환에 그 원인이 있는 것이 아니라, 현재 금융시장의 엄청난 팽창과 투기화로 인한 자본의 가치증식, 즉 투하된 화폐보다 더 큰 화폐를 획득하여야 하는 자본의 가치증식과정의 심오한 위기가 그 원인이다. 현재의 금융위기는 1960년대 후반의 생산자본의 이윤율 저하로 인한 가치증식과정의 위기가 세계적 차원의 구조조정을 거치면서 나타난 자본의 급속한 금융화가 그 원인이다. 이렇게 팽창된 금융자본은 새로운 생산자본 투자 지역을 찾아야 했고, 동시에 금융시장 자체의 성장을 방해하는 여러 가지 제도적 장치들을 정비했다. 이러한 금융자본을 중심으로 하는 자본운동의 지구적 차원의 공간 확대는 단일한 세계시장의 형성을 가속화하였다.

 

이러한 자본의 가치증식논리는 본질적이고 해결할 수 없는 내재적 자기모순을 가지고 있다. 한편으로 자본은 증식과정을 작동시키기 위하여 점점 더 많은 노동력을 상품의 생산과정에서 소비해야 한다. 노동력의 소비를 통한 화폐증식의 목적은 양적차원에서 이루어지기 때문에, 그 자체의 한계를 가지고 있지 않기 때문이다. 다른 한편으로 일상적으로 계속되는 경쟁은 생산의 합리화를 통하여 지속적인 생산력의 향상을 만들어 낸다. 이러한 과정은 결국 시간당 생산물의 양을 증가시키고, 따라서 필수노동시간을 축소하여, 과잉 노동력을 창출한다.

 

이러한 모순에 내재하는 잠재적 위기는 2차 대전 후-70년대 초반기의 성장속도의 가속화(생산력의 발전과 임금상승의 조응)로 인하여 계속적으로 미래로 연기되었다. 전 지구적 차원의 가치증식과정의 확대와 새로운 생산영역으로의 진출은 노동력에 대한 수요를 엄청나게 증가시켰으며, 이는 합리화의 효력을 상쇄시켰다. 하지만 IT 기술을 토대로 하는 새로운 생산력의 급속한 향상은 이러한 상쇄메커니즘을 폐기하게 만들었다. IT 기술은 거의 모든 산업분야에서 노동력을 축출하였다. 생산의 지구적 차원의 확대에도 불구하고, 지구적 차원에서 점점 더 많은 노동자들이 자본의 가치증식과정에서 불필요하게 만들었다.

 

가치증식과정의 위기는 우선 자본이 실물경제에서 더 이상 충분한 투자처를 찾지 못한다는 것을 의미한다. 더 나아가 생산된 잉여가치가 수용의 부족으로 인해 다시 현금으로 실현될 수 없다는 것을 의미한다. 이러한 상황에서 자본은 금융자본에서 새로운 도피처를 찾았는데, 이의 결과는 “의제자본”(투기와 신용)의 팽창을 가져왔다. 이러한 금융자본으로의 도피는 단지 위기의 연기에 불과하다. 과잉자본은 새로운 투자가능성을 찾았으며, 임박한 가치의 감소를 피할 수 있었다.

 

이러한 방식으로 이루어진 위기연기의 대가는 점점 더 심화된 잠재적 위기의 축적이며, 금융시장에의 극단적인 종속을 가속화하였다. 그리고 이러한 금융자본의 축적은 계속 진행되어야 했다. 어느 곳에서인가 거품이 꺼지면 정부와 중앙은행은 시중은행들과 투자가들을 구제하여 무담보 유동자산을 시장으로 쏟아 넣어 새로운 거품을 만드는 이외의 다른 방법을 찾을 수가 없었다. 따라서 정치권에서 투기의 포괄적인 억제정치를 논하는 것 자체가 속임수이며 그렇게 할 수 있는 능력을 가지고 있지 않다. 물론 일시적인 규제조치들은 가능하지만 종합적으로 보면 투기와 신용은 계속 진행되어야 한다. 왜냐하면 현재의 자본주의 시스템은 이러한 의제자본을 토대로 기능할 수 있기 때문이다. 따라서 현실정치가 이러한 현실에 부합되게 행하여지는 것도 그리고 금융시장의 역동성이 다시 회복되는 것은 전혀 우연이 아니다.

 

현재의 위기는 그 붕괴를 단지 국가채무의 엄청난 확대를 통하여만 일시적으로 막을 수 있다는 질적으로 새로운 국면을 보이고 있다. 이러한 이유로 위기는 국가의 재정위기로 나타나고 있으며, 이는 긴축재정을 통하여 사회의 프롤레타리아들에게 전가되고 있다. 점점 더 적은 노동이 더 많은 물질적 부를 창출할 수 있다면, 이는 그 자체로는 모든 사람들에게 행복한 삶의 가능성을 열어준다는 것을 의미한다. 하지만 자본주의 생산관계에서는 이러한 상황이 가치생산의 축소를 가져온다. 이러한 이유로 어떤 사회에서 “긴축할 수밖에 없는 상황”을 만들어내며, 이는 가치생산이 종속되어 있는 소비의 축소를 가져올 수밖에 없다. 이 거대한 부채는 자본주의에 의하여 창출된 생산 잠재력이 이미 자본주의적 사회의 논리로는 해결될 수 없으며, 자본주의적 부의 생산은 단지 폭력적으로 유지될 수 있다는 것을 의미한다.

 

위와 같이 현재의 자본주의 대위기는 전 세계적일 뿐만 아니라 역사적이기도 하다. 지난 몇 년간 드러난 거대한 부채더미는 1970년대 초에 이미 나타난 경제위기를 자본주의가 은폐하거나 늦추려했던 시도들의 결과였을 뿐이다. 또한 우리는 오늘날의 “경기침체”가 진정한 불황으로서의 본 모습을 드러내면서, 이것은 사실상, 1930년대의 대공황과 당시 세계를 제국주의전쟁으로 몰아갔던 위기와 같은 심각한 위기임을 인식해야 한다. 이 위기는 자본주의 체제가 역사적으로 쇠퇴하고 있음을 명백히 보여주고 있으며, 더욱이 오늘날의 불황과 1930년대의 불황사이의 차이는 오늘날의 자본주의는 위기에서 벗어날 어떤 수단도 갖고 있지 않다는데 있다.

 

 

3. 프롤레타리아 혁명의 전야, 사회주의냐 야만이냐

 

현재 우리는 이 세 번째 대위기의 초반을 통과하고 있다. 이 과정에서 전 세계적으로 노동자계급은 정리해고, 임금 연금 삭감, 노동조건의 후퇴, 비정규직화, 청년실업 만연 등 생활수준의 하락과 생존권 위협을 직접 받으며, 자본의 위기를 온통 전가 당하고 있다. 이러한 위기 전가에 맞서 전 세계적으로 노동자계급의 투쟁이 터져 나오고 있지만, 아직은 전체적으로 방어적 성격의 투쟁을 넘어서지 못하고 있다.

 

자본주의 체제는 아무리 깊은 위기라 하더라도 저절로 붕괴하지는 않는다. 자본주의의 ‘최종 위기’ 같은 것은 없다. 자본주의는 내재적인 붕괴 ‘경향’을 가지고 있지만, 저절로 사멸한다는 의미의 ‘자동붕괴’ 같은 것은 일어나지 않는다. 노동자계급이 앉아서 위기 전가를 당하길 거부하고 저항에 나서서 이 저항을 자본주의 자체에 대한 도전으로 끌어올려 자본가계급의 국가권력을 타도할 때만이 자본주의를 폐절시킬 수 있기 때문이다. 그렇지 않는 한 자본주의는 노동자계급을 희생시킨 폐허 위에서 언제든 다시 위기로부터 벗어날 수 있다.

 

현 위기는 첫 번째 대위기 못지않게 ‘사회주의냐 야만이냐’의 문제를 제기한다. 첫 번째 세계대공황 시기에는 사민주의와 스탈린주의, 코민테른의 타락 등 암흑의 반혁명과 침체의 시기, 노동자계급 지도력의 위기를 극복하지 못함으로써 자본주의의 숨통을 끊는 사회주의혁명으로 나아가지 못했다. 아니, 오히려 계급투쟁에 패배하여 파시즘과 전쟁 같은 야만을 불러들이고 이를 통해 자본주의는 다시 새로운 생명을 부여받았다. 이 시기에 자본주의가 아직 충분한 생명력과 역동적인 활력을 갖고 있었기 때문에 살아남은 것이 아니다. 이미 쇠퇴하는 자본주의, 제국주의 단계의 사멸하는 자본주의로서, “프롤레타리아 사회혁명의 전야”에 있는 자본주의였다. 다만 문제는 1917~1921년대 세계혁명의 패배이후 노동자계급의 지도력을 다시 세워내 혁명의 가능성을 살려내는 일에 실패했기 때문이다.

 

 

4. 자본주의 쇠퇴기, 노동자계급이 직면한 위험과 계급투쟁의 부활

 

노동자계급의 혁명은 결코 자동적으로 일어날 수 없는데, 이 혁명은 과거의 그 어떤 혁명보다도 더 높은 의식수준을 요구하기 때문이다. 1960년대 말 위기의 시기가 시작된 이래, 전 세계적으로 수많은 노동자들의 혁명적인 계급투쟁들이 있었다. 비록 이 투쟁들이 자본주의 체제를 전복하는 것에는 이르지 못했지만 분명한 계급투쟁의 부활을 알렸다.

 

하지만, 40여 년간의 위기 이후, 현재의 주요 자본주의 국가의 노동자계급은 1960년대 말과 같은 모습을 더 이상 띠지 않는다. 거대한 산업기지들과 강력한 계급투쟁의 집중 거점들은 사방으로 분산되었으며, 분업화된 시스템 속에서 노동자계급은 분열되고 위계화 되었다. 쇠퇴하는 자본주의하에서 노동자계급의 모든 세대는 지속적인 불안정 상태와 실업의 위험에 노출되어 있다. 더욱이 노동자계급의 가장 절망적인 층들은 범죄와 허무주의 또는 종교적 근본주의에 빠져들 위험에 처해있다. 자본주의 체제의 길고도 점점 더 첨예해지는 쇠퇴의 과정으로 인해, 노동자계급은 계급의 정체성을 다시 획득하고 사회의 지도력을 복원하여, 낡고 쇠퇴하는 자본주의 사회를 새로운 방향으로 이끌 수 있다는 자신감을 형성하는데  매우 심각하고 부정적인 영향을 받고 있다. 따라서 자본주의 착취에 대항하여 혁명적으로 투쟁하는 노동자계급의 모범이 없이는, 자본주의체제의 불평등하고 억압적이며 부패한 본질에 대항한 무수한 분노의 반응들이 있을 수 있겠지만, 그 자체만으로는 그 어떤 출구도 만들어낼 수 없다.

 

그러나 그 반대로 새로운 세대의 노동자들은 경제적 붕괴, 제국주의적 충돌, 환경파괴라는 자본주의의 암울한 미래에 대해, 아무 저항도 없이 수동적으로 이용당할 의사가 전혀 없다는 것을 그들의 직접행동을 통해 보여주고 있다. 이들의 새로운 투쟁과 직접행동은 자본주의 위기 상황에서 생활수준의 급격한 하락과 생존의 위협을 받는 수많은 프롤레타리아들과 노동자계급의 오래된 세대들을 자신의 주변으로 끌어 모을 수 있는 가능성을 보여주고 있다. 쇠퇴하는 자본주의 현재의 위기는 자본주의 주요 국가들에서 착취당하는 프롤레타리아 계급 대다수에게 이 썩어가는 자본주의 체제를 수호하기 위해 투쟁하고 죽을 만한 가치가 있다고 설득하고 동원해 낼 수 있는 지배이데올로기가 더 이상 존재하기 않는다는 점을 스스로 실토하게 만들었다.

 

2000년대 초반부터 고양되고 있는 노동자계급의 투쟁은 전 세계로 확산되어 1960년대 말의 계급투쟁의 부활과 같은 양상으로 전개될 충분한 가능성을 가지고 있다. 그리스, 스페인, 아일랜드, 이탈리아 등의 긴축반대 투쟁, 북아프리카 중동의 민주화 투쟁, 칠레의 공공교육 투쟁, 미국의 월가점령 투쟁, 중국, 인도, 방글라데시의 노동자 투쟁, 그리고 한국의 비정규직 노동자 투쟁 등이 이를 증명하고 있다. 이미 우리에게 프롤레타리아 혁명의 물질적이고 객관적인 조건은 충분히 주어져 있으며, 공산주의는 인류의 단순한 희망과 꿈이 아니라 역사발전의 물질적 필요성이며, 우리가 실현해야 할 역사적 과제임을 일깨워 주고 있다.

 

 

5. 자본주의에 저항하는 새로운 계급투쟁만이 노동자계급에게 답을 제공한다.

 

시위에서 광장점거로, 점거에서 대중파업으로 진화하는 유럽과 북미의 대중투쟁과 다르게, 한국의 계급투쟁은 여전히 사민주의와 조합주의 덫에 걸려있다. 특히, 현재 벌어지고 있는 진보대통합은 총선/ 대선 선거대응을 위한 개편이며, 서구에서 실패한 노동자 투쟁을 배신한 인민전선의 되풀이 일뿐이며, 노동자계급에 대한 배신행위이다. 그동안 이들의 대리주의 정치는 노동자계급의 자발적 투쟁분출과 계급투쟁의 혁명적 확산에 장애물이 되어왔다.

 

이러한 대리주의 정치를 극복하기 위해서는 노동자계급 스스로 정치와 혁명의 주체가 될 수 있는 자립적인 조직과 운동이 필요하다. 이러한 자립성은 계급의 자립적 조직인 노동자평의회와 계급의 정치조직인 혁명당과 강령으로 표현된다. 인민전선과 같이 노동자계급의 이해관계를 부르주아의 어느 정파의 이해관계와 혼합하고자 하는 시도들은 노동자계급의 혁명적 투쟁을 통제하고 잠재워 결국 노동자계급의 자립성을 저해하는 역할을 할 뿐이다.

 

자본주의 쇠퇴시기 계급투쟁을 성공적으로 수행하기 위해 노동자계급은 스스로의 조직 확장과 자기조직화를 통해 자신들의 투쟁을 전 계급적으로 통일시켜 나가야 한다. 이것은 자립적인 총회 조직들과 계급투쟁의 과정에서 창출되며 노동자들에 의해 언제나 선출되고 소환할 수 있는 아래로부터의 노동자 투쟁조직들을 통해 가능하다.

 

그렇다면, 끝 모를 자본주의의 위기상황이 더욱 깊어지는 현 정세에서 반자본주의 투쟁전선 구축과 혁명적 계급투쟁의 부활을 위해 무엇을 할 것인가?

 

첫째, 계급투쟁의 역사적 성과물인 혁명 강령이라는 무기를 들고 혁명당을 건설해야 한다. 노동자계급의 단련되고 혁명적인 부위들은 혁명당으로 집결하여, 자본과 국가를 효과적으로 압박하고 계급투쟁의 힘을 집중시켜야 한다. 노동자투쟁과 계급의식의 꽁무니를 쫒아 다니는 의회주의 정당들이 아닌 혁명당만이 계급의식을 혁명적으로 발전시키고, 노동자계급이 자신들의 정치적 전망을 설정하고 혁명적 무장을 준비하는 역할을 수행할 수 있다.

 

둘째, 갈수록 관료화, 자본의 기구화 되어가고 있는 조합주의와 노조운동을 넘어 아래로부터의 직접행동과 노동자민주주의가 철저하게 실현되는 투쟁조직, 총회조직을 건설해야 한다. 현재 유럽과 북미의 계급투쟁에서 빈번히 나타나고 있는 대중총회는 투쟁의 활력소가 되고 있다. 대중총회는 노동자들이 자신들의 투쟁의 주도권을 실제로 가져올 수 있고, 집단적으로 결정할 수 있는 노동자 민주주의의 진정한 공간이다. 대중총회는 모든 사람들에게 열려 있으며, 어떠한 조합주의와 계급협조주의에 의해서도 그 결정을 제한받지 않으며, 노동자 계급의 다양한 부문들을 통일시킨다. 노동자계급의 아래로부터의 민주주의와 직접행동을 기반으로 한 이러한 총회조직들이 바로 노동자계급이 각성하고 단결하여 한 단계 진전된 행동을 준비하고, 집단적 자심감과 자신들의 의지로 투쟁을 확장시킬 수 있는 공간인 것이다.

 

이와 같은 대중투쟁조직과 직접행동에 기반 한 계급투쟁의 확산만이, 조직된 노동자들의 계급성과 전투성을 되찾을 수 있는 계기로 작용할 것이다. 그리하여 대대적인 계급투쟁의 발발과 혁명적 계급의식이 만나 계급투쟁을 이끌 때, 공장의 담벼락과 업종의 울타리를 넘어, 정규직과 비정규직을 넘어, 전체 노동자계급을 단결시킬 수 있을 것이다. 또한 이러한 수평적 노동자조직들의 출현은 계급투쟁이 혁명적으로 전환하는 시기 노동자평의회를 현실화 시켜줄 것이다.

 

이미 진보정당들과 노동조운동의 상층부는 자본이 편재하고 분할해 놓은 노동자계급의 분리와 분열을 용인하거나 조장한 세력이 되어 버렸다. 이제 이들을 넘어서서 직접행동하고 더 넓게 조직하는 것이 노동자들의 단결과 투쟁의 동력을 회복하는 새로운 길이다. 이런 기운들은 투쟁하는 노동자들로부터 자발적으로 생성되고 있으며, 이것들이 커지면 커질수록 타락한 운동들은 더욱 반 노동자적 본색을 강하게 드러낼 것이다. 낡은 형식과 분열을 넘어 직접행동하고 계급의 단결을 만들어나가는 노동자들이 바로 노동자투쟁의 새로운 주체이다.

 

새로운 운동의 형태는 촛불투쟁, 희망버스 운동에서 보이듯이 자본주의 체제가 유지되는 한, 그리고 쇠퇴의 국면이 깊어질수록, 우리가 의도하지 않더라도 필연적으로, 계급투쟁의 과정에서 끊임없이 생성되고 소멸할 것이다. 자본주의 체제가 쇠락해 가는 것과 마찬가지로 자본주의 체제에 조응하며 유지되어 온 낡은 운동형식들은 이제 혁명성, 계급성을 상실한 채 몰락해 가고 있다. 아직 새로운 운동이 낡은 운동을 대체할 만큼 완전하게 소생하거나 전면화 되지는 못했다. 하지만 그것은 우리가 인내하며 기다린다고 그냥 와주는 것이 아니라, 대대적인 계급투쟁의 부활 속에서만 온전히 자리 잡게 될 것이다. 계급투쟁의 부활은 자본주의 쇠퇴가 만들어 놓은 물질적 조건(생존권 위협과 생활수준의 급격한 하락 등)에 의해 언제든 분출될 가능성이 있지만, 가능성을 현실로 바꾸는 것은 노동자계급의 계급적 자각이며, 혁명조직은 계급적 자각을 촉진시키는 역할을 해야 한다.

 

따라서 새로운 계급운동은 과거운동을 쇄신하거나 과거의 영광을 재현하려는 것에 국한되어서는 안 되고, 오히려 낡은 운동과 새로운 운동이 대립하고 있는 현재적 조건 속에서, 새로운 운동의 가능성에 근거를 두고, 끊임없이 계급투쟁의 방향을 자본주의 체제 자체에 도전하도록 밀어붙여야 한다. 계급투쟁의 부활과 자본주의 체제에 대한 도전만이 새로운 운동의 창출과 혁명적 의식의 생성을 가능케 하기 때문이다.

 

광장점거와 대중파업은 다시 한 번 노동자계급에게 혁명의 문제를 현실로 제기하기 시작했다. 자본주의의 타도를 목표로, 운동에 분명한 계급적 방향을 부여함으로써 그 문제를 해결하는 것은 노동자계급 자신에게 달려있다. 이것은 곧 계급투쟁과 혁명적 계급의식이 만나 의식적으로 수행하는 운동이며, 공산주의 강령과 이행요구에 입각한 정치투쟁을 의미한다.

 

현재 세계적으로 벌어지는 수많은 계급투쟁들 속에는 이미 “세계 혁명”을 요구하며 국경을 넘는 운동의 “확대”를 주장하는 슬로건들도 나타나기 시작했다. 많은 집회들에서 노동자국제주의를 위한 “국제”위원회가 만들어졌으며, 새로운 투쟁의 형식과 내용들은 국제적으로 전파되어가고 있다. 이제 한국의 노동자들도 낡은 사민주의와 조합주의의 덫을 걷어내고, 지금 당장의 직접행동과 노동자민주주의에 기반 한 대중투쟁으로, 자본주의 지배로부터 스스로를 해방시키는 길에 거침없이 나서자!

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

THREE CITIES, THREE OCCUPATIONS, ALL IN LESS THAN ONE WEEK

  • 분류
    계급투쟁
  • 등록일
    2011/11/10 10:09
  • 수정일
    2011/11/10 10:09
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

THREE CITIES, THREE OCCUPATIONS, ALL IN LESS THAN ONE WEEK

 

 

An account by a member of IP who visited Occupations in New York, Seattle and Vancouver. This account is a slightly modified version of a piece posted here on November 7, 2011.

 

Before I went to New York, I had only had a few hours’ experience at Occupy Vancouver. Some of it had been less than inspiring, including, on my last time there, having one person standing next to me (who I had never seen before) in a highly emotional state turn to me and very intensely tell me how there had just been a split amongst the core group of people involved in the organizing of the occupation, with the “liberals” (alternatively, the “hippie liberals”) having taken over, that it was a bunch of b.s. and that this was a terrible development. That was a little unsettling. I was, however, impressed with how the General Assemblies I attended were ‘facilitated’ so as to permit everyone present to participate, if they accepted and followed the agreed upon procedure, and to try to achieve maximum unity (the 90% consensus model). I was also impressed by the level of passion and openness expressed by the person who vented themselves to me. This thing was obviously very important to a number of these people.

 

Zuccotti Park in NYC was a different story. Even though the content of the first GA there I attended was uninteresting and not at all political, the ‘process’ was very impressive. The participants seemed more comfortable with and more proficient at the process. (Of course, they had been at it for almost a month longer than the ones in Vancouver.) And then their collective self-confidence – New Yorkers, you know – that was truly inspiring to experience. It seemed clear that this process was working well for them and they were proud of it. It really is something new, a new way of working together, in the most horizontal, the most “directly democratic” (beyond that, even, I would say) way yet realized by human beings. And the Occupy Wall Street encampment at Zuccotti Park is where it began. A sense that history was in the making here was felt but not easy to articulate at the time.

 

That sense became much clearer the next day. With the weather significantly warmer, there was a more relaxed, comfortable vibe to the place. (it was also afternoon, rather than evening.) This was several hours before the day’s GA. The person I was there with, a comrade, had been there a few times previously, and clearly felt very comfortable and confident about getting involved in any open discussion of interest to him. Various different conversations/discussions were going on in different parts of the park. In each case, we could listen in, ask what it was about, be informed about who it concerned/who was involved, and follow along if we wanted. It wasn’t long before we came across what I later learned is called the “Think Tank”. It is a place in the park, close to the middle, where open discussions on any topics can occur. One announces one’s topic, then sees who else wants to participate. It seems that the topics usually arise out of spontaneous discussions involving, initially, two or three people, which others then want to join into. My comrade and I participated in two of these discussions, one, which we stumbled upon, on capitalism vs. socialism, and another on how to find new ways to try to open people’s imaginations in a way that allows them to think outside of the restricted sphere of existence that the existing mass media, governments, educational systems, etc. enforce/impose on us. Each discussion involved about 8-10 people, with about 10-15 others just listening in. It was very informal – with just a “stacker” taking a list of people wanting to speak – but it seemed to work so well because people really wanted to make it work, rather than just get into another shouting match.

 

Here was real, serious discussion and debate, back and forth, with people really concerned to sharpen their views, to learn from each, in the most respectful way, among the widest variety of people (age, dress, style, race, sexual orientation, etc.) I think I had ever experienced. And although I was, unlike my comrade, slow to get involved, I did become actively involved and felt none of the unease and anxiety I would normally expect to feel in such a situation. Clearly, there was something big happening here, something that I had dreamt about being a part of for decades, something that has probably not existed in America since the late 1960s (when I was a child, but able to vaguely sense a feeling of ‘change in the air’). It was, and still is, exhilarating, to be sure.

 

My comrade suggested that I attend at least one session of one Working Group, since that was where a lot of good discussions occurred, and also where proposals put forward in the GA’s were initially worked out. I did attend one working group, on “visions and goals”, but only briefly, since the content at that time was not of interest, but again, the process used and its facilitation were impressive to witness. It was Halloween that day, and when I returned to Zuccotti Park from where the working group was meeting, it seemed that there was not an ‘official’ GA that evening; but there was a group of about 50-60 people near where the GA’s were being held holding an impromptu assembly, complete with various people dressed in very impressive Halloween costumes, including an impeccably dressed Emma Goldman. It was as much fun and convivial as it was serious and militant, but when we decided to hold a half hour break and then resume again, a few people announced different proposals for what to do during the half hour, including one to do a chain dance around the Merrill Lynch bull near the Bowling Green, another to go to the graveyard at nearby Trinity Church, across Broadway from Wall Street, to ask the spirits of the dead buried there for advice on what to do, to one to “go over there and discuss revolutionary politics.” Needless to say, I opted for the latter. It turned out this guy was still in high school and identified as an anarchist, and judged council communism to be a political tendency proximate to his. Another person self-identified as an anarcho-syndicalist. I didn’t label myself, but I did argue for the necessity of a Marxist critique and analysis of the economy and its crisis, after another person said it was essential for us to follow what’s happening in the economy, and to see how things are going to get a lot worse pretty soon – to which I wholeheartedly agreed. The discussion, involving at various times between six and twelve highly varied people, focused mostly on strategy towards the occupation movement from a revolutionary perspective. There seemed to be agreement reached that it was still too early to be focusing on ‘direct actions’ and trying to achieve any specific ‘gains’ or ‘victories’; that the principle aim should be, currently, to try grow the movement to involve as many people as possible from the ‘99%’, and to focus on discussion and mutual ‘education’, to get as many people as possible to recognize that our big goal should be the abolition of capitalism, and that we need to better understand how it dominates all our lives. It was one very satisfying discussion, one I won’t soon forget. That was pretty much it for that day at Occupy Wall Street, as it seemed all but a small number had left for Halloween events, including a massive Halloween march up Sixth Avenue.

 

The next day was a flight back to Seattle. The day after that I went to check out the Occupy Seattle encampment, which had recently been moved from Westlake Park, adjacent to the financial district in downtown Seattle, to Seattle Central Community College, in the Capitol Hill neighborhood, actually not very far away. It was about 1:30 p.m. when I got there, and it turned out that the little under a hundred people assembled there were holding a sort of rally to pep themselves up for what was coming. I had met one of the people who spoke at the rally, actually the best one in my estimation, at a recent public meeting. He’s a member of Seattle’s Black Orchid Collective and a very good public speaker. In fact, he was able to not only link the coming event to global capitalism, he also invoked the ever-increasing numbers of permanently unemployed that capitalism produces and contains in its various slums around the planet.

 

It turned out the coming event was a march up Seattle’s Broadway to a local branch of Chase Bank, owned by JP Morgan/Chase Bank, apparently one of the largest financial corporation in the world. I happily went along, up the street, with police escort. We chanted various slogans and chants along the way. Some were quite fun, including “Hey, hey, ho, ho, capitalism’s got to go!” and “Workers of the world unite, come and join the general strike!” (which was a reference specifically to the Occupy Oakland called strike, occurring that day). When we got to the bank branch we heard a few facts about JP Morgan/Chase Bank and its CEO, who was apparently in Seattle for a conference. It further turned out that about a half dozen people were already in the bank branch, ‘occupying’ it. We marched around the building a couple of times, chanting some more, and with a few people saying ‘their piece’ about banks. Several police with bicycles guarded the entrances to the building. It seemed that nothing much more was going to happen, for a while at least, but people remained, following what was going on inside. (1) At that point I had to leave, to catch a bus to Vancouver. I will say, though, that I was impressed by the militancy and the generally anti-capitalist tenor of the activity I saw and participated in that day in Seattle. The racial mix of the participants was also greater than what I saw in New York (even though it was impressive there too), and definitely more so than what I’ve seen in Vancouver.

 

I came back to Vancouver highly inspired by what I had experienced in New York and Seattle. I was convinced that there was ‘something in the air’ in America, that now is a time of soon-coming social change, and that many people’s consciousness was already changing, changing rapidly and massively, in the context of this very concentrated #OWS movement, and that we were likely still in the very early stages of it. Having had those American experiences, I was more comfortable and confident in participating in the occupation in my Canadian city, even if I find it difficult to shake my cynicism about the political attitudes and activities of my fellow citizens, especially those on the ‘left’. It could well be that the “liberals” have “taken over” control of Occupy Van., but it is still Occupy Van., part of the global #OWS (or “occupy together”) movement, and it is still open to everyone. I have participated, and tried to defend an anti-capitalist perspective, both in the GA’s and in informal discussions, and I have found other participants to be open to what I say and very respectful. I plan to stay involved and engaged, to defend and discuss an anti-capitalist perspective, specifically, an internationalist communist one, and to learn what I can from the others I engage with. I am also trying to get Occupy Van. to set up a ‘think tank’ like the one in Zuccotti Park.

 

E.

 

 

1. The Occupy Seattle action of Nov. 2 is described in this mainstream media article: http://blog.seattlepi.com/seattle911/2011/11/02/occupy-seattle-demonstrators-rally-at-chase-bank/

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

전 세계 노동자계급과 혁명적 공산주의자들에게 보내는 국제연대 메시지

  • 분류
    계급투쟁
  • 등록일
    2011/11/03 23:58
  • 수정일
    2011/11/03 23:59
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

전 세계 노동자계급과 혁명적 공산주의자들에게 보내는 국제연대 메시지 

 


사용자 삽입 이미지

우리는 지금 쇠퇴기 자본주의의 막다른 길목에서 수백년 유지해 온 체제가 단말마적 고통속에 마직막 숨을 거두려는 역사적 전환점에 서 있다.


  세계 대공황을 넘어 노동자를 포함한 인류를 야만의 삶으로 몰아 넣고 전쟁과 파시즘, 그리고 기아와 생태계의 파괴를 통하지 않고서는 더 이상 버틸 수 없는 지경으로 나아가고 있다.

 

  생명을 조금 더 연장하려는 자본주의 체제의 단기적 처방이 국가부채와 긴축, 실업과 정리해고, 복지의 파괴 등으로 이어지지만 그것은 더 큰 파국으로 가는 수순일 뿐이다.


  이와 같이 노동자 계급에 대한 자본의 전면적 공격은 필연적으로 인간답게 살려는 노동자들의 분노와 저항을 불러 일으켜 곳곳에서 계급투쟁이 격화되고 있다.

 

  이천년대 초반부터 고양되고 있는 노동자계급의 투쟁은 전 세계로 확산되어 68혁명과 같은 반격투쟁으로 나아가 혁명전야를 방불케 하고 있다. 그리스, 스페인, 아일랜드, 이탈리아 등의 긴축반대 투쟁, 북아프리카 중동의 민주화 투쟁, 칠레의 공공교육 투쟁, 미국의 월가점령 투쟁, 중국, 인도, 방글라데시의 노동자 투쟁, 그리고 한국의 비정규직 노동자 투쟁 등이 이를 증명하고 있다.

 

  이제 공산주의라는 대안사회가 인류의 단순한 희망과 꿈이 아니라 역사발전의 물질적 필요성이며, 우리가 실현해야 할 역사적 과제임을 일깨워 주고 있다.


  여기서 우리는 세계혁명을 향한 물질적이고 객관적인 조건이 주어지고 있음에도 불구하고, 또한 세계적인 노동자계급의 투쟁이 벌어지고 있음에도 불구하고, 맑스주의의 올바른 원칙과 전망을 세우면서 노동자계급과 함께 하려는 공산주의자의 조직인 당을 건설할 주체적 조건이 마련되지 않고 있다는 한계를 뼈져리게 느끼고 있다.

 

  오늘 우리는 세계혁명당이라는 새로운 인터내셔널의 건설을 향한 역사적 과제를 움켜 쥐고, 한국에서 공산주의자의 조직인 당을 만들려고 모였다. 이러한 움직임은 전 세계 노동자계급과 공산주의자들의 공통적 흐름이기 때문에 세계적 연대를 통해 토론하고 소통하며 공통강령을 마련하고 세계혁명으로 나아갈 것을 적극 제안한다.

 

 

세계 혁명당 건설 만세!
전 세계 노동자계급 혁명적 투쟁 만세!
전 세계 노동자여 단결하라!


 

2011년 10월 29일
노동자혁명당 추진모임

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

Return of the crisis: Part 2 - the nature and significance of the crisis

 

Return of the crisis: Part 2 - the nature and significance of the crisis

Aufheben #19 (2011)

 

Return of the crisis: Part 2 - the nature and significance of the crisis

The second part of Aufheben's analysis of the financial crisis.

 

Introduction

 

In Part I we gave an account of the immediately apparent causes and unfolding of the recent financial crisis, which began with the ‘credit crunch’ in the summer of 2007 and which culminated with near meltdown of the global financial system following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in the autumn of 2008. Here, in Part II of our article, we step back to consider the nature and significance of this crisis by looking at its deeper and longer term causes.

 

As we pointed out in the introduction to Part I, the recent financial crisis has brought forth a plethora of ‘radical theories’ purporting to explain the underlying causes of the recent crisis – mostly drawn from Marxism, but also from the more radical interpretations of the writings of John Maynard Keynes.1 Although these theories have many differences, and often come to distinctly different political conclusions, with a few notable exceptions, they have much in common. Firstly, nearly all of these ‘radical theories’ are essentially the same as those developed to explain the economic crises of the 1970s and 1980s. Secondly, most of these ‘radical theories’ can be described as being ‘stagnationist’: that is they are based on the proposition that capitalism is now in decline, and its underlying tendency is towards economic stagnation.2

 

During the 1970s and 1980s, when the advanced capitalist economies of North America, Western Europe and Japan were all being afflicted by slow economic growth, rising unemployment and high rates of inflation – a predicament that came to be known as stagflation – the proposition that capitalism had run into an impasse seemed almost self-evident; and certainly enjoyed a wide currency even amongst most bourgeois commentators and policy makers. The main contentious issue had then been how the underlying problem of economic stagnation could be resolved.

 

However, from the early 1990s there appeared to be a revival of capitalism with the beginning of what was to become a long economic upswing. The response of most ‘radical theorists’ was to argue that such a revival could only be short lived. Capitalism, it was argued, could now only provide a patina of prosperity on the basis of unsustainable debt and financial speculation. Sooner or later there would be an almighty financial crisis, the bubble of illusory prosperity would burst, and the underlying tendency towards economic stagnation would once again reassert itself. As a consequence, over the last twenty years the onset of any financial crisis of any significance has sent Marxists and radical Keynesians scuttling to their attics to bring down their ‘falling rate of profit machines’, ‘deficient effective demand detectors’ or other theoretical paraphernalia to demonstrate that this time the bubble had truly burst. Then, after each financial crisis had past and capitalism had resumed its upward path, they were obliged to put everything back into their boxes and sullenly take them back upstairs. As a result, with each successive financial crisis, the arguments of stagnationists had become less and less plausible.

 

The failure to account for the continuation of the economic upswing prompted some more critical Marxists, including ourselves in Aufheben, to question the received ‘stagnationist’ orthodoxy. This has led to the emergence a distinct heterodox current within Marxism that has argued that that the revival of capitalism was far from being illusory. Against the ‘stagnationists’, the ‘upswing’ theorists pointed out, the crises and restructuring of the 1970s and 1980s had succeeded in providing the basis for renewed capital accumulation.3 The decisive defeat of the working class in the USA and other advanced capitalist economies, the development of the ‘new economy’ of information and communication technologies and, above all, the integration of China and south-east Asia, with its vast reserves of cheap and acquiescent labour, into the US-centred global accumulation of capital had all served to bring about and sustain the long economic upswing since the early 1990s. As a result, by most measures profit rates returned to levels not seen since the long post war boom, there was steady economic growth, inflation was more or less conquered and unemployment had fallen.

 

Yet the financial crisis of 2007-8, which has plunged the world into the worst recession since the second world war, would seem to have turned the tables in the polemics between the ‘upswingers’ and the ‘stagnationists’. Although the ‘stagnationist’ theorists were still unable to provide a satisfactory explanation for the prolonged economic upswing, they could now claim to have been at long last vindicated – the almighty financial crash had, if rather belatedly, happened. The long upswing theorists, in contrast, now faced the problem of finding a convincing explanation for the financial crisis.


Given the problems of existing radical - and in particular Marxist - theories of the crisis, how are we to understand the nature and significance of the financial crisis and the current economic recession? Where should we begin looking for its underlying causes?

 

A major theoretical problem that we face is that although Marx provides us with perhaps the most incisive insights in understanding the crisis ridden nature of capitalism, he left no ‘unified general theory of crises’. Hence there has arisen a whole range of often conflicting Marxist theories of crisis, each one claiming support from particular passages in Marx’s ‘economic’ works. Yet even if we had an abstract ‘unified general theory of crisis’ it could only take us so far. Crises are by their nature historically specific. They are part of an open historical process in which the contradictions of capital’s development are brought to the fore and are forcibly resolved through class conflict. The resolution of one crisis then serves as the basis of the subsequent crisis. Each crisis has therefore to be understood in terms of the concrete historical circumstances out of which they arise. They cannot be simply explained a priori by some abstract schemas or formulae.

 

The basic problem of ‘radical theories’ of the current crisis, and this includes the ‘upswing’ theorists, is that they are still rooted in the analysis of the economic crises of 1970s. Of course there had been a number of financial crises in the 1970s, but these had been largely secondary if not rather peripheral to the fundamental problems afflicting capitalism at the time. After all it had been the sharp rise in the price of oil that had triggered the economic recessions of the 1970s not financial crises. As Marxists at the time had argued, these oil shocks had exacerbated the underlying economic and social problems caused by such underlying factors as the falling rate of profit, the increasing monopolisation of the economy and, of course, the breakdown of the post war class settlement and the consequent upsurge in working class militancy. As consequence, the financial system could be seen as little more than a parasitical excrescence on the real economy.

 

Yet, the recent crisis was first and foremost a financial crisis. After all, it was the crisis in the global financial system that can be seen as the cause of the subsequent world economic crisis. But neither the ‘stagnationists’ nor the ‘upswingers’ have developed an adequate theory of the development of global banking and finance over the past thirty years and have therefore been unable to provide an adequate explanation of the crisis.4

 

Of course, it is true that ‘stagnationist theorists’, particularly the radical Keynesians, have placed particular emphasis on the development of global finance and banking. In their polemics against the mainstream neoliberal economic theories of the role of finance and banking, they have certainly provided a powerful moral critique of the impact of the development of global banking and finance, by showing how it has both depressed the living standards of the working class and poor across the globe and caused havoc and economic instability. But in doing so they fail to grasp the positive role the emergence of global banking and finance has played in bring about the restructuring of capital accumulation and the rejuvenation of capitalism. Indeed, by retaining the conception of finance as a parasitical excrescence on the real economy, the ‘stagnationist’ theory of the emergence of global banking and finance, particularly in its more Marxist versions, has simply served to explain away the long economic upswing. As a consequence, their theory of finance has been rather ad hoc and one-sided.

 

On the other hand, in their polemics with the ‘stagnationists’, ‘upswingers’ have sought to emphasise the ‘economic fundamentals’ of the real economy - such as the restoration of the general rate of profit - that can be seen to have underpinned the long economic upswing. As a result the ‘upswingers’, including ourselves, have tended to overlook the importance of the rise of global finance and banking – and were thereby caught completely by surprise by the onset of the financial crisis.

 

In order to overcome the limitations of both the ‘stagnationist’ and ‘upswinger’ theories of the crisis we shall argue that it is necessary to consider far more closely the relation between the emergence and development of global banking and finance and the global restructuring of real capital accumulation that has occurred over the past thirty years. We shall argue that the emergence of global banking and finance has played a central role in the restructuring of global capital accumulation that brought about the long economic upswing. We shall then show how the continued development of economic restructuring of the real accumulation of capital over the past decade sowed the seeds for the crisis at the very heart of the global banking system.

Explaining the current crisis

On the eve of the crisis – the view from the cockpit


As we pointed out in some detail in part I of this article, on the eve of the current economic and financial crisis the masters of the universe, the plutocrats, their ministers and their minions could take a rather sanguine view of their world. Whatever political problems there may have been on the periphery with ‘Islamic terrorism’ and rogue states, the global capitalist system as a whole seemed to be in rude health. Although there were concerns at the growth of class conflict in China and elsewhere in Asia, and the European working class remained entrenched and resistant to ‘pro-market policies, for the most part social peace reigned.

 

The problems of stagflation that had beleaguered the previous generation of bourgeois policy makers had been overcome. Although it was considered important to maintain due vigilance, it could certainly be said that inflation had by and large been subdued. But more importantly the US had experienced more than fifteen years of, if not spectacular then certainly steady economic growth, which had only been briefly interrupted by the relatively mild economic downturn that had followed the dot.com crash. What was more, the first years of the new century had seen a broadening of world economic growth and prosperity. Newly ‘emerging market economies’ of less developed regions of the world, particularly Asia and Latin America, were now sustaining exceptionally high rates of economic growth; Japan had at long last begun to recover from its ‘lost decade’ of economic stagnation of the 1990s, the laggard economies of western Europe were at last beginning to pick up speed, and even Africa - the long forgotten continent – was showing signs of economic development for the first time in more than two decades.

 

Most bourgeois policy makers and commentators now accepted that the ‘tough and difficult decisions’ that had been taken to introduce neo-liberal policies had been necessary to lay the basis of the current era of economic prosperity. By helping to tear down the walls of ‘socialism’, protectionism and the national Keynesian economy, neo-liberalism had aided the birth of a new, reinvigorated global capitalism.

 

Of course, it could now be conceded, as the critics of neo-liberalism and ‘globalisation’ had vociferously pointed out at the time, that the immediate impact of unleashing ‘global market forces’ had produced an era of economic and financial turbulence that had often had a devastating economic impact - an impact that was largely borne by sections of the working class and the poor across the globe. Most of the advanced capitalist economies had been hit by the major economic recessions of the early 1980s and early 1990s. Russia and many of the eastern European countries had taken more than a decade to recover from the economic trauma of the neo-liberal ‘shock therapies’ imposed after the break up of the former Eastern Bloc. The 1990s had seen economic devastation caused by recurrent financial crises in Latin America and east Asia. Meanwhile, the 1980s and 1990s had seen the poorest countries, particularly those in sub-Saharan Africa, continue to groan under the onerous weight of debt inherited from previous decades.

 

Indeed, at the time, for many critics of neo-liberalism and ‘globalisation’ the dot.com crash in 2001 had heralded the culmination of the financial and economic turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s. The financial crises that had swept around the less developed parts of the global economy to such devastating effect had now returned home. It was thought that, with the bursting of the dot.com bubble, the US, the very heart of global capitalism, which through institutions such as the IMF and the World Bank had ensured that it had gained from the booms and busts elsewhere in the world, would finally obtain its comeuppance and would itself be plunged into a deep economic recession.

 

But, as the apologists for ‘globalisation’ and neo-liberalism could now point out, such predictions had been proved wrong. The bursting of the dot.com bubble, which saw $5 trillion wiped off the nominal value of shares of dot.com companies in the space of just six months, had certainly been a major shock to US-centred global financial system, and had threatened to bring about a severe economic recession in its wake. However, prompt action by the Federal Reserve Board and other central banks in cutting interest rates, combined with Keynesian-style cuts in taxes and expansion of public spending, had proved sufficient to minimise the impact of the dot.com crash. The financial system as a whole remained intact, while the consequent economic recession had proved to be mild and relatively short lived. Indeed, it could be argued that what the dot.com crash had served to demonstrate was the remarkable robustness and resilience of the global capitalist system.

 

Furthermore, by the spring of 2007 the dot.com crash could be seen as having brought to an end the era of financial and economic turbulence. There was talk amongst bourgeois commentators that the world economy had entered an era that future economic historians may well describe as the ‘great moderation’: an era of steady broadly based economic growth, low inflation and stable and orderly financial markets.

 

As such, for the apologists of neo-liberalism and global capitalism, the era of economic and financial turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s could be seen as merely the necessary birth pangs of a born again global capitalism that was now driving an ever expanding global prosperity in to the foreseeable future.

 

 

Prospects of the long upswing on the eve of the crisis
 

What bourgeois commentators viewed as the ‘great moderation’ was no patina of prosperity, which somehow simply hid the underlying tendency of modern capitalism towards stagnation. On the contrary, it was a view that was well-founded. The decisive defeat of organised labour in the advanced capitalist economies in the 1980s, combined by the rise of the ‘new economy’ and the integration of the vast armies of cheap and compliant labour in Asia into the world economy in the 1990s, had succeeded in bringing about a major restructuring of worldwide capital accumulation and, with this, a rejuvenation of capitalism. It has been the success of this fundamental restructuring of world capitalism that has led to the restoration of the rate of profit to levels not seen since the long post war boom, and these high rates of profit have consequently underpinned the long economic upswing that took off in the early 1990s and was only brought to an abrupt halt following the credit crunch of 2007.

 

Of course, against the triumphalism of the neo-liberal apologists of ‘globalisation’, it could be argued that the long upswing would sooner or later come to an end. The continuation of the long upswing had become increasingly dependent on the rapid rise of China as the distinct Asian epicentre in the US-centred global accumulation of capital. But the continued rapid accumulation of capital in China could not be taken for granted. Firstly, the rise of China had depended on its ability to provide a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant labour. Already by 2005 there had been signs that the demand for labour was in places beginning to run ahead of supply leading to a shift in the balance of power between workers and employers. After more than a decade of being static or even falling, there was growing evidence that wage rates in China had begun to rise. Secondly, the rapid economic growth of China had meant that world demand for food, fuel and raw materials was outrunning supply. The consequent rise in the price of food, fuel and raw materials not only threatened to squeeze profits in China but also, by causing an economic slowdown in the US and the west, led to a slowdown in the demand for Chinese exports, thereby curtailing the dynamic of China’s export led growth. Thirdly, China’s rapid and sustained economic growth had been dependent on state-directed investment and the insulation of the Chinese financial system from the volatility of global financial flows. With the Chinese authorities under increasing pressure from the US to open up its financial system, China could find itself going the same way as the Asian tigers of the 1990s. Foreign speculative investment could flood in, in an effort to take advantage of China’s vast surplus profits, and a speculative boom would result ending in an almighty crash.

 

Even if China managed to avoid such pitfalls and maintain its rapid accumulation of capital and economic growth, the long upswing in the US-centred global accumulation of capital would ultimately be limited. The rise of China had been able to sustain the long upswing because it had been based on a complimentary dynamic of accumulation with the US and other advanced capitalist economies. China, and behind it the rest of east Asia, has come to specialise in the production of cheap commodities that the US, and the other advanced capitalist economies, had either given up producing in the restructuring of the 1980s - such as textiles and clothing - or that they had never produced in the first place - such as computers, electronic toys and other digital and IT hardware. As such Chinese and Asian production did not overlap to any great extent with that in the west. Capital accumulation in China and Asia was therefore largely complimentary with that of the US and the western economies, allowing for a mutually reinforcing dynamic of capital accumulation between the west and Asia.

 

However, this complimentary dynamic of accumulation could be seen to hold within it the seeds of its own demise. Competition would inevitably reduce the world prices of Asian produced commodities to Chinese costs of production. As a result the surplus profits of Chinese producers would be eroded and the average rate of profit in China would tend to fall towards the world average.

 

However, so far this tendency towards a falling rate of profit in China has been limited by the active intervention by the Chinese state to restrict overinvestment. What is more, to the extent that this tendency has operated, it has been largely offset by Chinese producers moving into new but similar lines of production, for example by producing the latest, and more expensive, gadgets and gizmos. Yet, it can be argued, that the ability of China to limit or offset the falling prices and profits cannot be sustained forever. China will sooner or later have to move into the production of more sophisticated commodities, such as cars or machine tools. As a result its output will increasingly come into competition with that produced in the US and the other advanced capitalist economies. The largely harmonious dynamic of accumulation between China and the West will then give way to an increasingly competitive and potentially antagonistic zero sum game. It will be then that China will be obliged to challenge the US and make its bid for world economic hegemony, with perhaps dire consequences in terms of economic and military conflict.

 

But in 2007 the limits to the continued rise of China, and with it the rest of Asia, were only possibilities that were only beginning to loom on the distant horizon. In the short term the rise of China and the long upswing, which it was serving to sustain, seemed set to continue for at least another decade or so. Hence, for the time being the bourgeoisie and their minions rather sanguine view of the world could be seen as being more or less well-founded - even if it might prove to be more transitory than they would like to believe.

 

 

Conceptions of the significance and nature of crisis


As we pointed out in Part I of this article, by the spring of 2007 the mounting number of defaults on sub-prime mortgages in America had begun to be of some concern to the US monetary authorities. However, while the losses that the financial system was likely to suffer could be quite substantial and required monitoring, it had been assumed that the system would be robust enough to withstand the impact of such losses without too much trouble.

 

Few, if anyone, at the time foresaw that the collapse of the US sub-prime mortgage market would trigger a series of events that in less than eighteen months would lead to the near meltdown of the entire global financial system and as a consequence threaten the world economy with a great depression comparable with that of the 1930s. Even those Keynesian and Marxist critics who had argued that the housing bubble simply served to disguise the underlying tendency towards economic stagnation had failed to predict that it would end in such a severe financial crisis. For them the deflation of the housing bubble had been expected to lead to a decline in consumption, as homeowners could not borrow against rising house prices, and hence to a slowdown in the rate of economic growth in the economy, or perhaps even an economic recession.

 

But this brings us to the crucial question: if global capitalism was in the middle of a long upswing, with historically high rates of profits, how are we to explain the unforeseen financial crisis of 2007-08?

 

Most mainstream bourgeois commentators start with what would appear as the obvious fact that the current economic downturn was caused first and foremost by a financial crisis. It was the implosion of the financial sector, which had been triggered by the bursting of the US sub-prime mortgage market, which by impacting on what was otherwise a ‘fundamentally sound real economy’, has been the cause of the current ‘great recession’. As such there would seem to be little need to go beyond what can be seen as the immediate causes of the malfunctioning of the financial system, most of which could be seen as the result of policy errors on the part of governments or the monetary authorities.


Thus, as chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Alan Greenspan can be blamed for holding interest too low and for too long in order to cushion the impact of the dot.com crash. This, it can be argued provided the conditions for the plentiful supply of cheap and easy money that fuelled the housing bubble. The bursting of the sub-prime mortgage bubble can then be seen to be a delayed consequence of Greenspan’s decision to belatedly restore interest rates to more normal levels after 2005.

 

But although ‘errors’ on interest rate policy might go some considerable way to explaining what fuelled the housing bubble, and why it burst when it did, it is perhaps insufficient to explain how it was possible for rising defaults in one small corner of the American mortgage market to result in the near meltdown of the global financial system. Why was it that a financial system that had been supposedly so robust proved to be so fragile?

 

From the wilderness, Keynesians had long warned that the neoliberal policy of gradually dismantling the structure of regulation and supervision of the financial system that had been originally put in place after the Wall Street Crash of 1929 would sooner or later end in tears. Following the credit crunch of 2007, these warnings appear to have been vindicated and are now taken far more seriously by mainstream bourgeois opinion. Even the least chastened ‘masters of the universe’ are now obliged to admit, the process of de-regulation and liberalisation of financial markets and institutions had gone too far. The only issue being how far is too far, and hence how much re-regulation is required.5

 

The notion that the financial crisis was the result of a combination of excessive financial deregulation and low interest rates certainly provides a starting point for an understanding of the immediate causes of the crisis. Of course, it is a notion sufficiently broad to encompass various interpretations and political conclusions. It surely supports the mainstream bourgeois view that has emerged in the wake of the crisis that with minor adjustments to financial regulation and a more prudent monetary policy there can be a return to business as usual.6 Alternatively it may also support the view of more radical Keynesians that such misguided policy is the inevitable result of dominance of neoliberal ideology over the formulation of monetary, financial and economic policy that has been established over the past thirty years.

 

However, on closer inspection this notion that the financial crisis was the result of ‘policy errors’ has a number of loose ends. Firstly, the process of financial regulation has been going on for more than three decades. Why had this deregulation made the global financial system so fragile in 2007 when it had been sufficiently robust to whether the impact of the dot.com boom six years before? Was this because financial deregulation had passed some unidentified tipping point? Or was is it that low interest policy not only produced the housing bubble and bust that caused the shock that triggered the banking crisis, but also itself contributed to increasing the fragility of the financial system?

 

But emphasis on the interest rate policy of the monetary authorities has its own problems. As Alan Greenspan would no doubt protest, the ability of central banks to determine interest rates ruling in the economy is limited by the balance of supply and demand for loanable funds in the financial system. It is true that the monetary authorities can regulate the level of short term interests by means of ‘open market operations’, whereby central banks buy or sell short term government securities, and by setting the ‘discount rate’ at which they are prepared to lend to banks. Interest rates on debts and securities with longer maturities or with greater perceived risks are normally based on the short term rates set by the central bank. By raising or lowering its own discount rate, together with the short term rates on government securities, the central bank can normally raise or lower the entire structure of interest rates in the financial markets as a whole. But the central bank can only do this to the extent that the interest rates it seeks to establish are broadly in accordance with the overall balance of supply and demand in the ‘money’ and ‘capital’ markets.

 

Some of the more perceptive bourgeois commentators, economists and policy makers have long been concerned that international financial imbalances that have arisen since the late 1990s have given rise to what has become known as a ‘global savings glut’.7 This has led to a tendency towards an oversupply of loanable money capital in the world’s financial markets that has exerted downward pressure on interest rates.8 As such, it can be argued that it was not low interest rates that caused the flood of easy money and credit; but rather it was the flood of loanable money-capital that was the cause of lower interest rates.

 

Because of the emergence of a ‘global savings glut’, Alan Greenspan had been able to cut interest rates and sustain them at exceptionally low levels after the dot.com crash, despite a ballooning US government budget deficit that was greatly increasing the demand for loanable funds on the financial markets. However, when he sought to reverse his low interest policy in 2005, Alan Greenspan found that he was now working against the tide of the money and capital markets. The Federal Reserve Board succeed in more than doubling short term rates. However, longer term rates, weighed down by an oversupply of loanable funds, initially rose by far less than short term rates, and then began to fall back. As a result, between 2005 and 2007 there arose a flattening and even an inversion of the so called ‘yield curve’ – as the difference between short and long term interest rates became compressed, and at times even went negative.9

 

This inversion of the ‘yield curve’ can be seen to have given a further twist not only to the rapidly expanding housing bubble, but also to the increasing fragility of the financial system. Low interest rates had already reduced the profit margins that could be made on loans The commercial banks had responded by offsetting lower margins by increasing the volume of their loans – a sort of financial version of pile them high sell them cheap policy – seeking higher returns on more risky assets – that is known as ‘a search for yield’ - or move into investment banking by securitising its debt and selling it on, making profits from management fees and commissions rather than from interest payments. All of which can be seen to have been vital ingredients of the process that was to lead to the credit crunch of 2007 and the consequent financial crisis. The inversion of the yield curve following Greenspan’s decision to raise short term interest rates, meant that the profit margins of commercial banking operations, which depended on borrowing short term and lending long, became further squeezed, accelerating this process.

 

So, while monetary policy regarding interest rates might be blamed for accelerating developments that were to end in the big crunch, it was not the prime cause of the crisis. The prime cause can be traced back to the ‘global savings glut’ that had depressed interest rates and had produced an excess in the supply of loanable capital looking for profitable outlets such as the US mortgage market.

 

The view certainly goes beyond the notion that the credit crunch was merely a result of misguided policy. It also, as we shall see, serves as a point of departure in placing the crisis in a broader historical perspective. But, as far as it goes, this view still sees the crisis first and foremost as a financial crisis.

 

Now of course, from a Marxist perspective it may be argued that the sheer scale of the financial crisis, and its dramatic impact on the real economy, indicate that it was a manifestation of much deeper contradictions of global capitalism. After all did not Marx argue that the contradictions of capitalism burst ‘forth as monetary crisis’?10 Of course, it is from this conception of the financial crisis as being a symptom of deeper economic contradictions that has provided the entry point for the revival of the various radical Keynesian and Marxist stagnationist theories to explain the current crisis. Yet, the problem in resuscitating such theories to explain the financial crisis of 2007-8 is to find a plausible means of explaining away the long upswing of the past decade and half. If we reject the notion that the upswing was little more than an illusion, a patina of prosperity created by a series of asset bubbles that have now all gone pop, how do we explain the nature and significance of the crisis?

 

Of course the obvious logical way around this problem is to claim that the crisis reveals that, unbeknownst to anyone at the time, we have already passed a decisive turning point in the history of capitalism – the long upswing has in fact ended and we have now entered a long down swing of the Krondratiev cycle.

 

Yet there would seem to be little to suggest that we have entered a long down swing, other than the fact of the financial crisis itself. Indeed what evidence there is suggests the opposite, particularly for those who emphasise the determining role of the rate of profit. Although they have certainly been dented by the crisis, profit rates still remain at historically high levels in the US and elsewhere. Furthermore, although the levels of investment - and hence capital accumulation - fell sharply during the financial crisis, and still remain at subdued levels, what evidence there is suggests that what is holding back a recovery in investment is a lack of finance due to the continued retrenchment of the banks, rather than because of any lack of profitable opportunities for investment. Indeed perhaps what has been most remarkable about the current crisis has been the resilience and continued buoyancy of much of the ‘real economy’ despite the impact of the implosion of the financial system. Far from representing a critical turning point, the crisis at present appears far more as merely an interruption, or at most an inflexion point, in the continued ascent of the long upswing.

But this does not mean that the financial crisis was merely an accident, or the result of policy errors that have little or no necessary connection with the real accumulation of capital. On the contrary, we shall argue that the financial crisis must be grounded in the upswing itself.

 

The finance sector is neither an autonomous sphere independent of the ‘real economy’, nor is merely an expression of the real accumulation of capital. There is a complex inter-relation between the accumulation of moneyed capital and the accumulation of real capital. If we are to understand the underlying causes of the recent financial crisis we must consider the historical development of this complex inter-relation.

 

We shall begin by looking at the origins of the global financial system and the crisis of capital accumulation in the 1970s. We shall then consider the role the emergence of the global financial system played in the restructuring of capital accumulation and the restoration of profit rates in the 1980s and 1990s that was to provide the basis for the long upswing. Finally, we shall examine how further developments in restructuring of global capital accumulation since the late 1990s have given rise to the ‘global savings glut’, and with this the over expansion of global finance that resulted in both the ‘great moderation’ and its denouement in the current financial crisis.

The Rise of Global Finance

The post war boom and the repression of banking and finance


At least for the advanced capitalist economies of North America and Western Europe, the long post war boom of the 1950s and 60s – the ‘golden age of Keynesianism’ – had been a period of unprecedented economic growth, growing prosperity and social peace. At the time it had seemed that capitalism had at last been tamed. The violent booms and slumps that had afflicted much of the world in previous decades could now be considered a thing of the past. As the more radical Keynesians have emphasised, vital to this taming of capitalism had been the ‘repression of finance’ that had been established on the basis of the Bretton Woods agreement.

 

The Bretton Woods agreement is perhaps most famous for establishing the post war system of fixed exchange rates. In order to promote international trade the currencies of the major advanced capitalist economies were to be freely convertible, that is they could be freely exchanged with each other on the foreign currency markets. However, in order to prevent the competitive devaluation of currencies, which was widely seen to have severely exacerbated the world depression of the 1930s, it was agreed that all the governments party to the agreement, except that of the USA, should intervene in the foreign currency markets to maintain a fixed rate of exchange of their currency with the US dollar.

 

However, central to maintaining this fixed rate system had been the agreed right of governments to impose strict controls on the movement of money-capital across borders. These capital and exchange controls were designed to allow governments to prevent speculative flights of capital that might otherwise undermine their ability to defend the value of their currency.

 

By creating barriers to the international movement of money-capital, capital and exchange controls had severely restricted the development of international banking and finance. Most international monetary flows were closely tied to international trade. As such the international operations of banks and financial markets were confined to providing currency transactions necessary for the buying and selling of internationally traded ‘goods and services’, shipping insurance and credit to bridge lengthy shipping times.

 

Furthermore, what international capital flows there were mostly took the form of inter-governmental loans or direct foreign investment by transnational corporations. In either case banks and financial markets had played merely a secondary and supporting role. As a result the international flows of free loanable money-capital, not immediately tied to the current production and sale of commodities, was limited. International banking and finance remained in a rather embryonic form, confined to the cracks and crevices between the national jurisdictions of the monetary authorities.

 

With limited opportunities to take flight abroad, it was relatively easy for the monetary authorities in each of the advanced capitalist economies to domesticate financial capital. The highly restrictive regimes regulating banking and finance that had been put in place in the USA following the Wall Street Crash, and in western Europe due to the exigencies of resource planning during the war, were, for the most part, maintained.

 

The restrictions and compartmentalisation of banking meant that the primary role of banks became that of providing banking services and credit necessary for the efficient reproduction of industrial and commercial capital. As such, banks became regarded as little more than rather staid privately owned public utilities. Financial markets became dominated by institutional investors such as pension funds and insurance companies, which were charged with pooling and investing the savings of the middle and working classes. These institutional investors were primarily concerned with safe and steady long term investments, rather than with making a quick buck. These institutional investors therefore preferred to invest either in the shares of well established and dependable ‘blue chip’ companies or, more often than not, government securities issued to fund state borrowing.

 

The main players in determining capital accumulation were the large commercial and industrial monopoly corporations and conglomerates, which had come to dominate the advanced capitalist economies since the beginning of the twentieth century. Although it is true that these monopoly corporations had continued to raise capital through the issuing of shares or corporate bonds, for the most part their investment was financed through ‘retained earnings’ – i.e. out of their current or past profits.

 

Through the ‘repression of finance’ governments were able to ensure the financial and economic stability that was necessary to maintain the steady accumulation of real productive capital, and hence economic growth. Through the tight regulation of banking and finance governments were able to limit speculative bubbles that might otherwise disrupt capital accumulation in the real economy. Such constraints on finance also gave governments considerable freedom to use Keynesian monetary and fiscal policies to maintain a steady growth in effective demand conducive to large scale and long term investments carried out by the monopoly corporations. The monetary authorities were able to keep interest rates low in order to maximise ‘retained earnings’ and hence high levels of productive investment. At the same time, despite low interest rates, governments were able to borrow from the captive financial markets to fund the large scale public investments in the nation’s economic and social infrastructure necessary to support real capital accumulation.

 

As a result, banking and finance, in each of the advanced capitalist economies, was subordinated to the national accumulation of real productive capital. This ensured steady economic growth, rising profits and wages, near full employment, increased public services and the establishment of the welfare state central to sustaining the various post war class settlements and hence social peace.

 

 

The rise of international banking and finance
 

The 1970s saw a major transformation of international banking and finance that was to bring an end to the ‘repression of finance’. There were three main causes of this ‘liberation of finance’: first of all there was the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, secondly the recycling of ‘petrodollars’ following the ‘oil shock’ of 1973, and finally the rapid growth of ‘offshore banking’. Let us briefly consider each in turn.

 

As we have seen, in accordance with the Bretton Woods agreement, the governments of the advanced capitalist economies, other than the USA, had been obliged to maintain a fixed rate of exchange between their currency and the US dollar. The US government, for its part, had in turn agreed to fix the value of dollar to gold. To do this the US guaranteed to convert on demand dollars into gold at the rate of $35 for each ounce. At the time of the signing of the Bretton Woods agreement in 1944 this obligation to convert US dollars into gold at a fixed rate had been inconsequential for the US government’s economic and political policies. As a consequence of the war, Fort Knox held around three quarters of the world’s entire stock of gold. But more importantly, with much of Europe devastated by war, American industry faced little competition. As a result throughout the 1950s the US enjoyed a substantial trade surplus, as its exports flooded into Europe. This had led to a severe dollar shortage in western Europe. Foreigners, particularly Europeans, wanted US dollars, now the undisputed world currency, not gold.

 

However, with the recovery and reconstruction of western Europe and the rise of Japan, US industry faced increasing competition. The US trade surplus declined at the same time as foreign direct investment by US transnational corporations in Europe increased. By the 1960s the dollar shortage had begun to become a dollar glut. The threat that the overhang of surplus dollars held by foreign banks and governments might be presented for conversion into gold now began to place onerous constraints on the freedom of US economic and political policy. The arms race with the USSR, the escalation of the Vietnam War, together with the need to secure social peace at home through expensive social programmes such as President Johnson’s ‘Great Society’, required unprecedented levels of government spending. But such high levels of government spending only served to worsen the outflow of US dollars.

 

In 1971, in order to cut himself free of such constraints, President Nixon suspended the US government’s commitment to convert dollars into gold and unilaterally announced a 10% devaluation of the dollar. This precipitated the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. By 1973 attempts to shore up the system had been abandoned in favour of a system of managed floating exchange rates, in which governments only intervened in the foreign currency markets to limit excessive fluctuations in the value of their currencies.

 

The abandonment of fixed exchange rates opened up profitable opportunities for speculation in the day-to-day fluctuations of exchange rates on the foreign exchange markets. It also opened up profitable opportunities for banks to sell ‘financial products’ that would allow exporters and importers to hedge against adverse movements in the value of currencies. The collapse of Bretton Woods thereby certainly contributed to an increased internationalisation of the operations of the national banking and finance systems of the advanced capitalist economies.

 

But the collapse of the fixed exchange rate system did not immediately lead to an end to capital and exchange controls or the barriers separating the national banking and financial systems of the advanced capitalist economies. Far more important in this was the recycling of petrodollars, caused by the oil shock of 1973, and the consequent development of offshore banking.

 

In 1973 the world economy was rocked by OPEC quadrupling the price of oil. As a result of the sharp rise in oil prices, the low cost oil-producing sheikdoms of the Middle East suddenly found themselves awash with US dollars with little to spend it on other than yet more palaces and camels. As a consequence, they began depositing their surplus oil revenues in Eurodollar accounts of European banks and European subsidiaries of American banks, which had grown up to avoid US capital and exchange controls. These accounts were particularly attractive, not only because they offered high rates of return, but also because they were out of the reach of the US monetary authorities, and were therefore less likely to become impounded by the US government in the event of a political or diplomatic crisis. With the stream of ‘petrodollars’ flooding into their Eurodollar accounts the western banks, which operated within the Eurodollar system, now had to find somewhere to invest this money that could provide them with sufficiently high returns to cover the returns they offered on their Eurodollar deposit accounts. With the US and other advanced capitalist economies plunged into recession following the oil shock, the banks had to look beyond their traditional clientele of other banks and transnational corporations. As a result they began making large scale loans to ‘third world’ governments.

 

This recycling of ‘petrodollars’ brought about a dramatic expansion in both the scale and complexity of the international finance and banking system. Whereas previously it had been a rather marginal and arcane activity for the major US and other western commercial banks, international banking operations now became a substantial potential source of profits. As a consequence, banks rapidly expanded their international operations, bringing about a profusion of specialist international financial intermediaries, and the development of new ‘financial products’ and markets in order to facilitate the increased volume deals.

 

But this was not all. In order to expand their share of international banking and finance, the western banks began opening up subsidiaries that were nominally registered in small ‘third world’ states that offered both minimal taxes on financial transactions and lax banking regulations. The banks were then able to offer their domestic corporate and more well-heeled individual depositors the option of transferring their deposits to their ‘offshore’ subsidiaries. With economic and political uncertainty and falling returns in the US and western Europe, the risk of placing funds in minimally regulated banks was for many depositors more than offset by the higher returns such offshore banking offered - particularly as these banks had the implicit backing if things went wrong of their reputable parent banks.

 

Loanable money capital accumulated in the advanced capitalist economies could now flow into the channels of international finance that had been carved out by the recycling of petrodollars. The growth of offshore banking allowed the banks to evade regulatory controls that had inhibited the free movement of money-capital across national boundaries. In doing so offshore banking prised open the cracks in the national regulation of finance, weakening the walls that had been erected to separate the various national banking and financial systems from the largely unregulated and unconstrained international banking and finance.

 

As a result of the break up of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates, the recycling of petrodollars and the development of offshore banking, the 1970s saw an explosive growth in international banking and finance. By the end of the 1970s the volume of international flows of loanable money capital had grown to such a scale that they threatened to overwhelm any attempt to control it on the part of governments and monetary authorities. In 1979 the levees began to break.

 

Firstly, in May 1979 Margaret Thatcher came to power committed to dismantling Keynesianism and the post war social democratic settlement in Britain. Under the slogan ‘you can’t buck the [financial] markets’, one of her first moves in this direction – the significance of which is often overlooked - was to scrap capital and exchange controls, allowing the free movement of money and capital in and out of the British economy. Within the next few years all the advanced capitalist economies had been obliged to follow Thatcher’s lead. As a consequence, the barriers to the free movement of capital across borders were torn down.

 

Secondly, in October 1979, Paul Volcker, the newly appointed chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, announced a sharp about turn in US monetary policy. Following the second ‘oil shock’, which had seen a doubling of oil prices, there had been growing fears that the consequent increase in the US trade deficit could trigger an uncontrollable speculative flight of capital from the US and, with this, a collapse of the US dollar on the foreign exchange markets. In order to ward off such a threat Volcker abandoned the last vestige of Keynesian monetary policy of maintaining low interest rates. US interest rates were forced up leading to a huge influx of loanable money-capital into the USA and a soaring dollar. In order to limit the outflow of money-capital to the US, the other advanced capitalist economies were obliged to follow suit and raise their own interest rates and, in doing so adopt monetarist economic policies.

 

As such, 1979 marked the end of Keynesianism and the triumph of what was to become known as neoliberalism. Governments and monetary authorities gave up attempting to subordinate banking and finance to the national accumulation of real productive capital through restrictive regulations. The free movement of capital was now to be promoted. As barriers to the free movement of finance capital were progressively dismantled the national banking and financial systems became merely segments of what was to become a US-centred global banking and financial system, in which money-capital could freely flow in search of the highest returns.

 

 

The ‘liberation’ of finance and the stagnation of the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’.


As radical Keynesians such as Susan Strange and Howard Watchel have pointed out, concerted action on the part of governments and monetary authorities could have perhaps prevented the explosion of international banking and finance. Thus, for example, following the rise in oil prices in 1973, there could have been an international agreement that would have allowed for petrodollars to be recycled through official intergovernmental channels, overseen by such bodies as the IMF and the World Bank. Furthermore, the monetary authorities in the US and elsewhere could have imposed new financial regulations to clamp down on the subsequent growth of offshore banking, and thereby nipped it in the bud.

 

For radical Keynesians, the lack of political will to take such action is seen, at least in part, as the result of the growing political influence of finance and banking over the formulation of economic policy. The economic crisis, which had for them been primarily caused by the sharp rise in the costs of oil, food and raw materials in the early 1970s, had led to a crisis in confidence in the continued efficacy of Keynesian policies. Taking advantage of this, banking and financial interests had been able to push towards the reversal of the ‘Keynesian revolution in economic policy’ and, with this, the progressive abandonment of the ‘repression of finance’.

 

Furthermore, as the radical Keynesians pointed out, the consequent rapid growth of international banking and finance in turn brought with it a corresponding increase in the political power and influence of the bankers and financiers. By the end of the 1970s they had reached a position where they could seize control over state policy. Keynesianism was deposed and replaced by neoliberalism. As a result, over the last thirty years economic policy across the world has been driven by the overriding special vested interests of bankers and financiers, much to the detriment of the rest of society, particularly the poor and the working class.

 

Many Marxists might well agree with radical Keynesians on this. However, for most Marxists, the sharp rise in the costs of oil, food and raw materials in the early 1970s had only served to exacerbate and bring to a head a much deeper crisis in the process of capital accumulation that had underpinned the long post war boom. As such the ‘crisis of Keynesianism’ had not been due to the transient problems of adjustment following the impact of the ‘oil shocks’ and rising ‘commodity prices’, but had been due the fact that capitalism had reached an impasse, which manifested itself in recurrent economic and political crises. There could therefore be no return to the ‘progressive capitalism’ of the ‘golden age of Keynesianism’.

 

As the Marxist French of the Regulation School, and many others have pointed out, the long post war boom had been driven by the rapid expansion of the mass assembly-line production of standardised consumer durables – epitomised of course by the production of ‘automobiles’ and known accordingly as the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’. It may be admitted that Keynesian policy and the consequent ‘repression of finance’ had served a vital role in facilitating the large scale and long term investments in building and equipping the car factories, steel plants and petro-chemical complexes that had been necessary for the post war ‘Fordist’ economy. However, by the late 1960s these investments had begun to result in an over-accumulation of productive capital.

 

As a result there began a long term tendency for the general rate of profit to fall. Attempts to reverse the falling rate of profit faced formidable, if not insurmountable, problems.

 

Firstly, as we have seen, the large scale investments necessary for the rapid expansion of ‘Fordist’ mass production had been carried out by commercial and industrial monopoly corporations and conglomerates. As a consequence, these corporations had accumulated substantial amounts of fixed capital in the expansion of productive capacity. But by exploiting their monopoly position they were able to resist any scrapping of excess productive capacity and the devaluation of their fixed capital that this would entail. Thus there was little scope to remedy the over-accumulation through the scrapping of excess capital and the devaluation of accumulated capital.

 

Secondly, after nearly two decades of near full employment, the organised working class in the advanced capitalist economies had established strong entrenched positions that allowed them to thwart attempts to reverse the falling rate of profit through increasing the rate of exploitation. The ability of the working class to defend existing terms and conditions and working practices meant that attempts to increase the productivity of labour, through such means as raising the pace and intensity of production or through introducing new technology, had become increasingly limited.

 

Furthermore, attempts by capitalists to restore profits by raising prices only served to solicit demands for higher wages to compensate for the rising cost of living. This resulted in a price-wage spiral and thus accelerating inflation.


The falling rate of profit, coupled with the growing social instability and class conflict that it helped to exacerbate, resulted in a decline in productive investment and thus a slowdown in the real accumulation of productive capital. In order to offset this slowdown in capital accumulation and to maintain economic growth and full employment, governments sought to use Keynesian fiscal policies to ‘spend their way out of the crisis’. However, this merely aggravated inflation and put upward pressure on interest rates and led to mounting state debts.

 

Marxists could then argue that, in the face of falling rates of profit, economic stagnation and increasing political and social instability, the capitalists typical response to such problems was to take refuge in financial speculation. But banking and finance only served to redistribute not create surplus value. As such it was ultimately a zero sum game, in which capitalists sought to gain at the expense of other capitalists. Thus, the rise of the political and economic power of finance and the corresponding ideological turn to neoliberalism, could be seen as merely a symptom of the underlying stagnation of capitalism.

 

However, whatever the disagreements at the time between radical Keynesians and Marxists about the causes and significance of both the release of finance and the turn to neoliberalism, it could be agreed that it could only have a devastating economic and social impact, which seemed to offer little in the way of a long term to solution to the economic stagnation of capitalism. Indeed, following Volcker’s adoption of monetarist policies, the US, and consequently the rest of the world, was plunged into a deep recession. Manufacturing industry, in particular, was decimated, and unemployment soared to levels not seen since the Great Depression of the 1930s.

 

Although the decimation of industry served to eliminate excess productive capacity and thereby halt the fall in the rate of profit, at the time it seemed far from sufficient to resolve the problems of capitalism’s stagnation. Capital, it appeared, had nowhere to go after the ‘Fordist mode of accumulation’. The computer, information and communication technologies, which were to provide the basis of what was to become known as the ‘new economy’, were still in their infancy. At the same time, the concentration of Fordist capital accumulation in the advanced capitalist economies during the post war era had left much of the rest of the world undeveloped and lacking the economic infrastructure that would enable a large scale relocation of capital.

 

The recovery from the recession of the 1980s was only brought about by Ronald Reagan’s adoption of an economic policy that has often been described as being ‘military Keynesianism’. Following his election in 1980, Reagan abandoned the policy of detente and set about accelerating the arms race with the USSR. Military spending rocketed at the same time as Reagan slashed taxes on the rich and large corporations. As a result the US government budget deficit soared from 2.7% in 1980 to 6% of GDP in 1984. This quasi-Keynesian deficit spending provided a huge stimulus to the US economy allowing it to pull the rest of the world economy out of recession.

 

However, at the time, this appeared as merely a short term palliative to the underlying problem of economic stagnation. It could be persuasively argued that the US could not sustain such high deficits, particularly when the money that was being borrowed was being economically wasted on unproductive militarily expenditure and increased conspicuous consumption for the rich. It could be concluded with - what has become a repeated refrain amongst both Marxists and radical Keynesians up until the present day - that the economic recovery was based on an unsustainable bubble of debt.

 

This argument seemed to be confirmed with the return of the world economic recession at the beginning of the 1990s.


Meanwhile the sharp rise in interest rates and the economic recession at the beginning of the 1980s triggered the ‘third world’ sovereign debt crisis. This was followed by the biggest stock market crash in 1987 and the US Savings and Loans crisis of 1990. As such, the ‘liberation’ of finance and banking could be seen to have only served to increase economic and financial instability.

 

By the end of the 1980s many Marxists could argue that the restructuring of capital accumulation had largely failed. The only way out for capitalism was a cataclysmic event such as a world war that could bring about a mass destruction of capital and allow capital accumulation to take place on renewed footing. After all it could be argued that it had been the Second World War that had prepared the way for the long-post war boom. Yet with hindsight we can see how the basis for a new long upswing was already being put in place. We must now look a little closer at the role the emergence of global finance and banking had in this.

 

 

Global banking and finance and the foundations of the long upswing

 

The growth of international banking and finance meant that an increasing proportion of shares of the large monopoly corporations were being held by investors looking for the highest short term returns. Even a rumour that the next quarter’s profit forecast might prove disappointing could now lead to speculative flight from a company’s shares and a collapse in its share price. Such a fall in its stock market valuation could then put a company at risk of a hostile take-over bid.

 

As a result company managers were obliged to concentrate on the short term profit performance of the company in order to maintain high dividend payouts and keep the valuation of their company high. The ‘maximisation of shareholder value’ became an overriding imperative. Managers could no longer put off difficult decisions. They had to face down opposition from their workforce and push through rationalization, downsizing and outsourcing of ‘non-essential’ functions in order to make their companies mean and lean. Capital sunk in the company had to be sweated to earn the highest return. Failure to do so would mean being replaced by a new management team appointed by the new owners who would be ruthless enough to force through the necessary changes.

 

This competitive pressure exerted by the financial markets had two distinct effects. Firstly, it ensured that management kept wage rates down and work rates high in order to maximise profits. Secondly, by ensuring companies were ‘mean and lean’ it meant that any excess capital could be liquidated and siphoned off into the financial markets, in the form of higher dividend payments, to swell the pool of free loanable money-capital.

At first the growing pools of international loanable money-capital had ended up flooding into the USA to finance Reagan’s massive budget deficit. Although at the time it might seem the emerging global financial system was simply financing Reagan’s profligate tax cuts and military spending programmes, with hindsight it can seen that in doing so it was playing an important, if indirect, role in bringing about the restructuring of capital accumulation.

 

Firstly, the escalation of the arms race eventually brought about the fall of the ‘evil empire’ thereby opening up whole new regions of the world for capital accumulation in the following decades.

 

Secondly, and more immediately, the military programmes inaugurated by Reagan, particularly the Strategic Missile Defence Initiative or ‘Star Wars’ as it was commonly known, effectively served as a hidden state investment programme. Through Star Wars military spending was channelled into funding the vast research and development of the computer, information and communication technologies that was necessary to provide the foundation for the take off of the ‘new economy’ in the 1990s.

 

Under the Bush (Snr) and the Clinton administrations, concerted efforts were made to wind down the huge deficits that had been inherited from the Reagan era. By the end of Clinton’s second term the US budget deficit had been eliminated. However, by then whole new spheres of investment opportunities had opened up providing ample demand for the supplies of free loanable money-capital flowing through the global banking and financial system. Firstly there were the new emerging economies of Asia and secondly there was the emergence of the ‘new economy’.

 

 

Global finance and the ‘newly emerging market economies’
 

As we have previously mentioned, the long post war boom, driven by the ‘Fordist mode of capital accumulation’, had been largely confined to the USA and the other advanced capitalist economies. Most international capital investment had taken the form of foreign direct investment within the developed world – and was predominantly by US transnational corporations setting up production in Western Europe.

 

As a result, as third worldists at the time often lamented, much of the ‘third world’ was relegated to primarily producing raw materials and agricultural products, which lacked the economic dynamism provided by ‘Fordist’ manufacturing industries. As a consequence, capital accumulation in the core had only a minimal impact in promoting economic growth and development in the economies on the periphery of the western world.

 

There had, of course, been attempts by various ‘third world’ governments, often in alliance with the USSR and other state capitalist countries of the Eastern bloc, to pursue national autarchic industrialisation strategies. With varying degrees of success, governments in the periphery had sought to promote the development of domestic manufacturing industries by protecting the home market from manufactured imports. But by the 1970s these ‘import substitution’ strategies had largely run out of steam due to both limited home demand for manufacturers and by a lack of access to modern production technologies. Nevertheless, this limited development of manufacturing industries in the more developed ‘third world’ had created a substantial pool of cheap and compliant labour, which was both, accustomed to the disciplines of wage labour and possessed the necessary skills for factory production. Indeed, with much of the world population outside the heartlands of western capitalism there was, in the longer term, a vast potential for the global expansion of capital beyond the advanced capitalist economies.

 

However, there had been formidable barriers preventing western capital exploiting the vast potential pool of labour in the ‘third world’. Firstly there had been numerous political problems. Thus for example, any transnational corporation considering investment in a ‘third world’ country, particularly one that had been committed to a nationalist industrialisation strategy, faced the risk that the government might at some time in the future nationalise their investments.

 

But, perhaps more importantly, there were the sizeable economic barriers to the globalisation of capital. If transnational corporations were to set up production they first of all needed dependable communication and transport networks, and they needed reliable sources of power, gas and water, but the economies of the ‘South’ often lacked such basic economic infrastructure. Although there might be substantial savings in labour costs, given that labour in the ‘third world’ was far cheaper than that in the transnational corporation’s home country, this would usually be more than offset by the large scale investments required for the construction of the economic infrastructure necessary before production could even begin.

 

Secondly, the transfer of productive capital required the existence of an economic milieu of small- and medium-sized enterprises that could provide the vast range of ‘goods and services’ necessary to maintain day-to-day production and to feed, clothe and house the company’s workforce. In the absence of such local suppliers, a transnational corporation would have to ship everything required to maintain production itself. This would often not only have been prohibitively expensive, but also a logistical nightmare.

 

As a consequence, it had only been in agriculture and the extractive industries, such as mining, where climatic or geological factors meant there was no option but to site production in the less developed world, that the transnational corporations of the US and the western world had ventured south. Even then, as third worldists and development economists at the time often pointed out, foreign direct investment for the most part only created economically developed enclaves, since the transnational corporations only invested in economic infrastructure that was strictly necessary for their own operations.

 

In the 1970s the seeds were sown for what was to become the ‘globalisation of capital’, which was to see the outflanking of the entrenched positions of the working class in the advanced capitalist economies. And, as we shall see, the emergence of what was to become the global banking and financial system was to play a central part in the relocation of productive capital. First of all, in the face of falling profits, growing political instability and an increasingly intransigent working class in the heartlands of capitalism, transnational corporations began to look upon the prospect of relocating production, particularly manufacturing, to the more developed economies in the periphery far more favourably than they had previously. Secondly, there was the impact of the recycling of petrodollars through the emerging international banking system.

 

As the ‘sovereign debt crises’ of the early 1980s were to reveal all too clearly, much of the petrodollar loans made by banks to ‘third world’ governments had been frittered away either in fuelling local arms races or else on grand prestigious public projects that turned out to be white elephants. Nevertheless, a substantial amount of these loans had been used to promote a switch from an import substitution industrialisation strategy to an export-led strategy. Previously, any attempt to promote export-led growth had run into the problem of a lack of US dollars. Any large scale investment programme necessary to develop export industries would result in an initial surge in imports of raw materials and other commodities necessary to set up production. This would lead to a sharp rise in the outflow of US dollars to pay for them until production was up and running and the dollar revenues from export sales began to flow in. With limited dollar reserves a government attempting to promote such an investment programme would soon find itself with a serious currency crisis on its hands. However, with western banks falling over themselves to lend them petrodollars they had been able to lift this dollar constraint.

 

Furthermore, by borrowing from western banks ‘third world’ governments were able to finance the construction of the economic infrastructure necessary to encourage investment from western transnational corporations. This direct investment then brought with it access to both the most up to date production technology and to the transnational corporations well-established sales and distribution networks in their home markets.

 

Thus, the 1970s saw the beginnings of the relocation of the more labour intensive ‘Fordist’ lines of production to what were then known as the newly industrialising countries of the capitalist periphery. However, the world recession of the early 1980s saw a sharp fall in the demand for the manufactured exports from these countries. At the same time, as export revenues fell, the costs of servicing the huge debts that had built up rose with the sharp increase in interest rates. This produced the ‘third world’ sovereign debt crises of the early 1980s. With many western banks having had their fingers burnt in this crisis they became far less inclined to lend to ‘third world’ governments and the whole process of recycling petrodollars came to a halt.

 

Nevertheless, pressures on transnational corporations to exploit the opportunities that had been opened up to relocate production to the periphery were now to intensify. Firstly, the high exchange rate of the US dollar in the early 1980s, made many manufactured commodities produced in the USA uncompetitive. There was therefore a strong incentive for US transnationals corporations to continue to relocate production, particularly to nearby Central and South America. Then, with the sharp fall in the US dollar following the Plaza Agreement of 1985, and the corresponding sharp rise in the exchange rate of the Yen, many Japanese transnational corporations were prompted to transfer the more labour intensive stages of the production of commodities destined to be exported to the USA to neighbouring South Korea and Taiwan, whose currencies remained pegged to the US dollar and where there were plentiful supplies of cheap labour. As a result the momentum for the relocation of production was maintained through the 1980s.

 

As we have seen, by the late 1980s the US government had set about unwinding the huge budget deficits run up under Reagan. The demand for loanable funds to finance the deficit began to fall at the same time as the liquidation of capital in the old established Fordist industries of the US and other advanced capitalist economies continued to increase supply. As a result there was a renewed interest on the part of global banking and finance in what were to become known as the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of Asia and Latin America. Western banks began making loans not only to ‘third world’ governments and transnational corporations to facilitate the relocation of production, but also to local banks in Asia and Latin America. Using their local knowledge and business connections, these local banks were then able to make loans to a wide variety of small- and medium-sized firms crucial to developing the economic milieu of local suppliers that could then further encourage direct investment from transnational corporations and thereby hasten the accumulation of capital.

 

This dynamic process was given a further twist by Western banks securitising these loans and selling them on to other financial institutions interested in buying liquid assets that had offered high returns. This gave rise to what became known as the emerging market economies securities market that served to funnel short term investment flows into financing the rapid export led growth of Latin America and, in particular, east and south-east Asia.

 

 

Global finance and the emergence of the ‘The New Economy’
 

As we have seen, the dramatic increase in military spending under Reagan had, in part, served as a huge hidden state investment programme that had funded the rapid development of the new information, communications and computer technologies. State investment, driven by military objectives and imperatives, was central to startling advances both in the processing power and miniaturisation of hardware and the increasing sophistication of software, which was necessary in providing the foundations of what was to become the ‘new economy’. However, in the subsequent development of the commercial applications of these new technologies the role of private finance and investment was to play a far more significant role.

 

In the early 1990s it was still far from certain how the emerging new technologies would develop, how they would be used and how they could be made profitable. Investment in the emerging ‘new economy’ promised high returns but high risks. A situation well suited to ‘casino’ operations of high finance and banking. Banks were prepared to lavishly fund promising ‘new tech’ start ups and then float them on stock markets, selling shares to investors looking for high risk-high return investments. The flood of loanable money capital from banks and the financial markets then served to fuel the take off of the ‘new economy’ that occurred in the 1990s.

 

The take off of the ‘new economy’ had an important impact on the ‘old economy’, which in turn provided growing demand for ‘new tech’ products. Administration costs could be cut with the computerisation of offices, computer aided design reduced research and development costs, computerised stock control and faster and more efficient communications increased the turnover of capital and reduced amount of stocks that could be held, in these and in many other ways the commercial application of the new technologies served to increase the rate of profit in the ‘old economy’. Furthermore, the ‘new economy’ opened up a whole new range of commodities and ways of selling them from which profits could be made.

 

So, as we have seen, the emergence of global finance and banking played an important, but by no means an exclusive role, in the restructuring of world capital accumulation that provided the basis for the restoration of the general rate of profit and hence what was to become the long economic upswing.

 

First of all, the ‘liberation of finance’ helped galvanise capital to launch a counter-offensive against the working class at the level of both the state, through the implementation of neoliberal policies, and at the level of individual capitals, through rationalisation, redundancies and the intensification of labour. Secondly, the emergence of global banking and finance served to liquidate capital fixed in low profit industries, particularly in the old Fordist industries located with the advanced capitalist economies. And thirdly, by facilitating the transfer of this liquidated capital to potentially high profit locations and industries, the emergence of global banking and finance helped to open up new spheres of profits with the emergence of the ‘new economy’ and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ in Asia and elsewhere.

 

During, these early stages in the restructuring of global capital accumulation, particularly between the late 1980s and late 1990s, the demand from these new spheres of investment for free loanable money capital tended to outrun the supply. The period was characterized by a relative dearth of loanable money capital flowing through the global banking and financial system. An indication of this undersupply of money capital was the persistence of relatively high interest rates through this period. But perhaps more significantly it was reflected in the frequent specific financial crises that typify this time. As the limited amount of footloose loanable money capital swashed around from one specific area of investment to another it gave rise to booms and busts in each of these areas. Thus, for example, there was the savings & loans crisis in late 1980s, the Mexican crisis in 1994, the Asian crisis in 1997, the Russian crisis in 1998 and the dot.com crisis in the US stock market in 2001.

 

However, the restructuring of capital was to be taken to an altogether higher level with the rise of China. This opened up a new phase in the economic upswing that, as we shall now see, was typified by an oversupply of loanable money capital flowing through the global banking and financial system.

 

 

The Rise of China

In 1992 Deng announced a major shift in Chinese economic policy that was to prove to be of world historical significance. Abandoning more than forty years of autarchic economic development, China was to open its doors to large scale foreign investment. As a result foreign investment flooded in to China, rising from negligible levels in 1992 to more than $50bn (equal to 5% of China’s GDP) ten years later, driving China’s economic transformation into the new ‘workshop of the world’.

 

The Deng announcement certainly came at a propitious time. The economic boom of east and south-east Asia, which had begun in the late 1980s, was now in full swing. Attracted by cheap and compliant labour, foreign investment had flooded into Asia, first of all to the more developed countries such as Taiwan and South Korea and then, as labour shortages and wage rises began to take hold there, to what became known as the Asian tiger economies; the Philippines, Indonesia, Thailand, and Singapore. This incessant movement of capital in search of cheap labour had brought about both a disintegration and de-nationalisation of the production process in Asia. The production process of commodities was broken up into distinct stages; the more labour intensive stages being relocated to where there were lower wages and less skilled labour, while the more capital intensive stages were retained in those countries with relatively higher wages but a more skilled and reliable workforce. China, with its vast potential reservoirs of cheap and compliant labour, and its close proximity, appeared as an obvious next step for international investors. China could easily fit into the rapidly emerging Asian economy. Component parts produced across Asia could be transported for the more labour intensive stages of assembly in China before being shipped off to the US and western markets.

 

However, the Chinese state was determined not to fling open the doors for foreign investments and invite any fly by night investors or speculators in search of a quick return. Only foreign capitalists that were prepared to make long term investments directly in the development of real production were to be welcome. Typically such direct foreign investment was to take the form of joint ventures, co-owned by predominantly US transnational corporations and the Chinese state.

 

For their part the transnational corporations were to provide the design of manufactured products and advanced western technology embodied in plant and equipment necessary for their production. They were to provide business connections that could open the door to the distribution networks of the US and other western markets. And particularly important in the early stages of China’s integration into the US-centred global accumulation of capital, they were to provide working capital in the form of US dollars in order import the raw materials and other inputs necessary to get the joint venture off the ground. For its part the Chinese state was to provide a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant labour, along with investment in the economic infrastructure required for the efficient production and transportation of the commodities produced by the joint ventures.

 

Once the joint venture was up and running, the combination of western design and production technology, and a plentiful supply of cheap and compliant Chinese labour, certainly offered a win-win situation as far as the Chinese state and its ‘First-world chauvinist’ partners in their ‘imperialist citadels’. With costs of production far below any competitors elsewhere in the world, these joint ventures could sell well below the ruling world market price and still make handsome returns. The transnational corporation’s share of the joint venture’s profits would be sufficient to provide them with a rate of profit substantially higher than the general rate of profit they could expect to earn in the US or elsewhere in the advanced capitalist economies. But, at the same time, the Chinese state could ensure that it could appropriate the lion’s share of the returns in the form of taxation and its share of the joint venture’s profits, which could then be ploughed back in furthering capital accumulation and economic development in China.

 

In 1997 the economic boom in east and south-east Asia was brought to an abrupt halt. The rapid expansion of manufacturing industries had by the mid-1990s begun to outstrip the development of the economic infrastructure that was necessary to support it. Land and property prices had begun to rise sharply in the industrial and commercial areas of the region. The flows of short term foreign investment drawn from the western banks and the global financial markets, which, alongside direct foreign investment by transnational corporations, had originally helped finance the accumulation of real productive capital, now began to switch into property speculation. As a result, the rate of growth in manufacturing output, and with it Asian exports had begun to slow down. At the same time the windfall gains produced by the speculative property bubble to a large extent ended up being spent on luxury consumer imports. As a consequence, by 1997 the leading Asian tigers were heading for large and persistent trade deficits.

 

Nevertheless, it is possible that the trade deficits could have been sustained long enough to defuse the speculative boom if the Asian economies had been able to continue to attract enough US dollars in the form of foreign investment to cover the outflow of US dollars due to the trade deficit. But for the banks and financial markets the emerging ‘new economy’ in the US was now opening up safer if not more profitable investment opportunities for foreign investors, which now began to look like a better bet than carrying on investing in the Asian tigers in the hope that their economic imbalances could be sorted out without the bursting of the speculative bubble.

 

Pivotal to the Asian export-led boom had been the stability provided by fixed exchange rates, and it was with an exchange rate crisis that the wheels of the boom fell off. An essential ingredient to the success of the tiger economies had been the commitment of each of their governments to maintaining a given parity at which their national currency would exchange with the currency of both the world and their biggest export market - the US dollar. At the same time, with each currency pegged to the US dollar they were in effect pegged to each other creating an Asian system of fixed exchange rates.

 

During the height of the boom, when US dollars were flooding in, due to both high levels of foreign investment and rising revenues from export sales, this commitment had been easy. All the monetary authorities had to do was to buy up the surplus dollars with their own currency and deposit them in the nation’s foreign currency reserves. There was effectively no limit to preventing an appreciation of their currency against the dollar because they were always free to issue more of their own currency with which to buy dollars. Now, with a dollar drain, in order to defend a fixed exchange rate against the pressure towards the devaluation of their currency against the US dollar, they now had to be prepared to enter the foreign exchange markets and to buy up the surplus of their own currency with dollars, thereby depleting their dollar reserves. The monetary authorities were therefore limited by the amount of their reserves of dollar holdings.

 

Although the Asian tiger economies had together accumulated substantial reserves preventing their currencies appreciating against the US dollar during the height of the boom, it was now a depleting hoard divided up into several national reserves. It now became a plausible possibility that a well timed and sustained speculative attack on a currency of any one of the Asian tigers could be sufficient to exhaust that country’s national dollar reserves hoarded at its central bank, and force a sharp devaluation of its currency against the US dollar – thereby, of course, providing a killing for any speculator brave enough to lead the charge by betting early on such an outcome.

 

As it turned out, it was Thailand that proved to be the weak link and was the first to succumb to a speculative attack in July 1997. Tasting blood, the pack of currency speculators then turned on the Philipines. Within weeks the Asian system of fixed exchange rates had collapsed. Those foreign investors that could made for the exits. No longer able to borrow on the global financial market, Asian banks were no longer able to roll over their foreign debts and were forced to call in their loans to Asian businesses. Thus the exchange rate crisis rapidly developed into both a financial and economic crisis in the region, which was to see widespread bankruptcies, a sharp slow down in economic growth and tens of millions of workers plunged into abject poverty after losing their jobs.

 

At the time there had been serious concerns amongst Chinese policymakers that the shock waves from the financial and economic crisis elsewhere in Asia might wreck China’s still fledgling export-led growth strategy. However, with hindsight the Asian crisis provided a timely opportunity for China to establish itself as the hub of Asian manufacturing production. As we have seen, unlike its neighbours, China had avoided being reliant on the footloose short term investments provided by the western banks and the global financial markets. With its strict controls over capital flows and the convertibility of its currency, China was sheltered from the worst of the financial storm that was wreaking havoc elsewhere in the eastern Pacific. Amidst the economic chaos besetting its Asian neighbours, China now shone forth as a haven of stability. Overcoming any surviving misgivings that, as a still nominally Communist state, it might in the future revert to type and nationalise foreign investments, transnational corporations now focused their attention on China’s vast profit potential. Whereas the rest of the east and south-east Asian regions suffered a collapse in foreign investment in the aftermath of the crisis, China suffered merely a brief pause in its growth. China could now establish itself as the principal destination for foreign investment destined for the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia.

 

With foreign direct investment pouring in, and with the Chinese state ensuring approaching 50% of China’s GDP was reinvested, both in the expansion of export-manufacturing production directly, and in the state’s vast infrastructure construction programme that was necessary to sustain rapid economic development into the future, China had within less than five years established itself as the heart of the emerging Asian ‘tiger’ economy. At first this rise to prominence had at least been partly at the expense of its neighbouring ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia. In the aftermath of the crisis, stages in the chain of manufacturing production, particularly the final assembly stages, previously undertaken elsewhere in Asia, were now relocated to China. Soon, most Asian manufactures destined for export to the US and other advanced capitalist economies, were at least partly produced in China. At the same time as establishing itself as the funnel through which Asian manufactures poured in the US and western markets, China began a concerted ‘move up the production chain’ to take on earlier more capital intensive stages of the production process. As a result China was able to secure a growing proportion of the value of the manufactured exports produced in the east and south-asian economy.

 

This displacement of value production from its Asian competitors was increasingly offset by two factors. Firstly, the rapid and sustained growth in the volume, and hence the total value, of Asian exports being funnelled through China to the US and the West increasingly compensated for the declining proportion of this total value falling to China’s neighbours. Their slice of the cake might be diminishing relative to that of China, but this could be largely offset by the growth in the total size of the cake. Secondly, China’s ambitious infrastructure construction programme – that was to see industrial cities the size of London being brought into being in a matter of few years – required huge quantities of oil, coal, timber, steel and concrete, along with various other raw materials, necessary to build road and rail networks, power plants and other utilities, as well as to construct houses, offices and factories. Before the Asian boom, many of the Asian tiger economies had specialised in the production of such raw materials. Hence it was relatively easy for them to revert back and expand such production to meet China’s growing demand.

By the early years of the new millennium, China had become not only the heart but the locomotive of the region. China’s economic growth was serving to pull it neighbours out of the recession that had followed the 1997 financial and economic crisis. However, China had not only established a complimentary dynamic of accumulation between itself and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia. It had also, as we have previously mentioned, established a similar, and perhaps far more important, dynamic of accumulation with the USA.

The essential complementarity in the economic relation between the USA and China was certainly recognised and reflected in the rather sanguine view taken on the part of the US bourgeoisie to the rapid emergence of China as a major economic powerhouse in the world. Of course, there were concerns dating back to the early stages of the Asian boom in the 1980s, that the import of cheap Asian manufactured goods was displacing American industry and making American workers redundant. Now, with the rise of China, this stream of Asian imports had become a flood. But it could be countered that to the extent that imports from China were driving American industry out of business, this was for the most part only hastening the demise of those American industries that had long been in a state of decline anyway. What was more, a large proportion of the commodities now being imported from China was hardware for the information and communication technology that had not been previously produced in the USA in the first place because they had yet to be invented. Indeed, it is perhaps true that overall the displacement of American industry and jobs arising from Chinese competition has been marginal. Although, of course, the threat of outsourcing to China has proved a potent weapon in the armoury of the capitalist in keeping down the demands of the American working class in recent years.

There were plenty of other good reasons for the American bourgeoisie to welcome the rise of China. The flood of cheap manufacturers from China had played a valiant part in the defeat of inflation. The high returns from their joint ventures in China bolstered the profits of US transnational corporations and enhanced the dividends distributed to their large American shareholders. Not only this, as we shall see in more detail shortly, the Chinese monetary authorities could be said to have played a key role in allowing the US government and the Federal Reserve to take action to mitigate the economic downturn following the dot.com crash.

If this was not enough, it was the rise of China that had served to substantially broaden the US-centred global accumulation of capital. By the middle of the last decade, rapid Chinese economic growth had meant that world demand for fuel, raw materials and food was beginning to outrun supply. As a result, world prices for such ‘primary commodities’, which for nearly two decades had been depressed, began to rise. This was a boon for those economies that produced such commodities in the less developed world - not only in Asia, but now also in Latin America and even Africa - who could now export more at a better price. But it was not only economies on the periphery of world capitalism that benefited from the rapid economic growth in China. China’s growing demand for more sophisticated manufactures, such as machinery, machine tools and heavy vehicles, had begun to haul even Japan out of its long period of stagnation. The rise of China had served to raise the rate of accumulation across the globe, and in doing so could be seen as opening up plenty of investment opportunities.

Yet despite all this, there had certainly been worries amongst bourgeois commentators at the time concerning the sustainability of the growing ‘financial imbalances’ that had arisen along with the rise and continued expansion of China. To understand the relation of the rise of China to the financial crisis it is necessary to turn and consider these financial imbalances more closely.

The rise of China and the supply and demand of loanable money- capital
For the neoliberal ideologist China’s great economic transformation over the last two or three decades is due to China abandoning a ‘socialist command economy’ in favour of a ‘free market capitalism’. But, as we have seen, what has been essential to the continued rise of China has been its rejection of what is usually taken as the epitome of free market capitalism - the financial markets. China’s rapid capital accumulation has been financed first and foremost through state-directed investment. The Chinese state has ensured that the most of the surplus value produced in China has been reinvested in China. To the extent that Chinese capital accumulation has been dependent on external financing this has taken the form of foreign direct investment by transnational corporations, rather than by borrowing from western banks or issuing debt on the global financial markets.

As such the rise of China has had little direct impact on the demand for loanable money-capital in the global financial system. But it can be argued that it has served to increase the demand for loanable money-capital indirectly at least in two distinct ways. Firstly, in raising capital to invest in joint ventures in China, the transnational corporations will certainly themselves have resorted to the financial system by issuing shares and corporate bonds or else taking out bank loans. The long delivery times involved in producing in China and selling in the USA also require short term credit from banks or the financial markets. However, the bulk of the investment funds will have come from retained profits; at first largely from the profits made in the US and subsequently, increasingly from ploughing back profits previously made in China.

 

Secondly, and more indirectly, to the extent that it has stimulated capital accumulation elsewhere in the world, the rise of China can be seen to have increased the demand for loanable money-capital. This is perhaps particularly the case for those emerging market economies that, unlike China, have been more open to allowing an inflow of investment funds from western banks and the financial markets.

 

Yet overall, given its scale, the emergence of China as the Asian epi-centre of the global accumulation of capital has had a relatively limited impact on the demand for money-loanable capital from the global financial system. Yet this is not so much the case when we turn to consider the supply-side. To see this we have to look more closely at the ‘financial imbalances’ that have emerged between China and the US.

 

 

Trade and financial imbalances
 

As we have mentioned, an essential ingredient to the success of the Asian boom had been the commitment on the part of the governments of east and south-east Asia to maintaining a fixed exchange rate between their own currencies and the US dollar. However, this policy objective had not been merely confined to these Asian economies. Across the less developed world those economies seeking to follow the Asian example of export-led growth had, with varying degrees of success, attempted to tie the value of their currencies to that of the US dollar. The financial crises that hit Asia and Latin America during the 1990s had served to disrupt this tendency towards a system of fixed exchange rates amongst the ‘emerging market economies’. However, since then this tendency has resumed, with China emerging as the keystone in this new system of fixed exchange rates. This gave rise to some bourgeois economists to declare the emergence of a new Bretton Woods system of exchange rates.11

 

As China became the main portal through which cheap Asian manufactures were pouring into American markets, its trade surplus with the USA grew rapidly. But up until 2002 this had been more than offset by its trade deficit with east and south-east Asia. As such, the US dollars that came into China in the form of export revenues and foreign investment were spent on the purchase of component parts and other intermediary products necessary to produce the commodities bound for export to the USA, and the raw materials and products necessary to maintain its vast infrastructure construction programme. In 2002 China’s growing trade surplus with the USA overtook its Asian trade deficit. From then on China found itself with a growing surplus of dollars that placed upward pressure on the dollar value of the yuan. In order to maintain its fixed exchange the Chinese monetary authorities were obliged to buy up the surplus dollars. China’s foreign exchange reserves, which were largely made up of US dollars, soared. In little more than five years China’s monetary authorities had accumulated more than $2 trillion in its foreign exchange reserves.

 

However, the Chinese authorities, like all other monetary authorities facing a surplus of dollars, did not simply stuff their vaults full of greenbacks. The dollars were used to buy up US treasury bills. In this way the Chinese monetary authorities were able to ‘put their reserves to work’ earning a modest interest by investing in safe security that could easily be converted back into dollars in an emergency. At the same time, the dollars were recycled back to the USA, helping the US government to finance both its own debt and the American economy’s growing trade deficit with China.


This recycling of China’s dollar surplus proved to be quite timely since it allowed the USA to pursue the expansionary fiscal and monetary policies that were necessary to mitigate the financial and economic aftershock of the dot.com crash. Between 2002 and 2004 the US government had moved from a budget surplus amounting to more than 2% of US GDP to a 4% deficit as it cut taxes for the rich and increased spending to ward off a severe economic recession. With China’s growing appetite for US treasury bills, the US government found it relatively easy to finance this sharp increase in the government deficit without pushing up interest rates. Indeed, with the short term money markets swollen by the recycling of China’s dollar surplus, the US monetary authorities had been able to drastically cut interest rates.

 

Of course, by allowing the US to reflate its way out of recession, China was able to sustain its growing exports to the USA, and hence its export-led growth. This recycling of China’s dollar surplus certainly seemed to have ensured a mutually beneficial economic dynamic between the USA and China. However, there were certainly concerns expressed amongst bourgeois economists at the time over the sustainability of this dynamic, most of which focused on the problem of mounting US debt that this involved.

 

The US had been running a substantial trade deficit with the rest of the world for more than two decades. In order to cover this trade deficit it had been necessary that financial inflows into the US had grown faster than outflows. Indeed, as long ago as the late 1980s the US had turned from being the world’s largest creditor nation to being its largest debtor nation. As a result, by 2005 US debt accumulated by foreign corporations and governments amounted to more than 75% of the annual GDP of the USA. The issue was how much longer the USA could continue to borrow, particularly now that much of this borrowing was being used to finance unproductive government expenditure and a debt fuelled consumer boom. Or as it was more prosaically put: how much more could Americans continue to spend more than they earned? Would not the interest and other payments on these debts sooner or later reach unsustainable levels?

 

Now, it could be pointed out that although American debt accumulated by foreigners had reached 75% of US GDP, American investments abroad had grown to 50% of GDP. Net debt was therefore a far more comfortable 25% of GDP. Furthermore, US investments abroad tended to bring significantly larger returns than investments in the US. This was even more so given that much of the debt was now being accumulated by China along with other emerging market economies in the form of low interest US treasury bills, as a result of them seeking to maintain fixed exchange rates. This differential in the rate of returns between US investments abroad and foreign investments in the USA meant that the US economy taken as a whole could run up a substantial net debt before it reached the slippery slope of ‘Ponzi’ financing where it would in effect be borrowing more money in order to pay off the interest on existing loans. Even when it had reached this point of moving into ‘Ponzi financing’, it would still take a number of years before the burden of debt would become a serious problem.

 

By 2007 there were strong indications that the ‘financial imbalances’ were being unwound. Capital accumulation in the US had begun to pick up speed, taking up the strain of maintaining economic growth. Rising tax revenues from the expanding economy had reduced the government budget deficit, while rising exports was reducing the US trade deficit with the rest of the world.

 

Nevertheless there remained concerns amongst more conservative bourgeois commentators, who viewed China more in terms of a future threat rather than as a probationary member of the ‘international community’ that was offering lucrative profit opportunities. For them the issue was not so much the size of the mounting debts of either the US government or the US economy as a whole – and hence the problem of paying them back at some point in the future - but rather the issue was the danger posed by the fact that a large and growing proportion of these debts were held by the Chinese state. In 2000 China accounted for half the trade surplus of the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of east and south-east Asia with the rest of the world. By 2005, with most of east and south-east Asian exports being funnelled through China, it accounted for virtually all the region’s trade surplus. As a result, the Asian dollar surplus had become increasingly concentrated in China. In recycling this dollar surplus, the Chinese monetary authorities had become by far the largest purchaser of US government treasury bills. Thus the day to day financing of the US government had become dependent on the continuing goodwill of the Chinese state.

 

In the event of a political confrontation between the USA and China – say for example due to a flare up over the security of Taiwan – it was argued that the Chinese could exercise considerable leverage over the USA by threatening to stop buying its treasury bills. Alternatively the Chinese monetary authorities may, for purely economic reasons, decide that they had accumulated more than enough dollar holdings to insure themselves against some unforeseen economic crisis and they would be better off buying securities issued by Japanese and European governments that offered a superior rate of return.

 

For whatever reason, whether political or economic, a decision by the Chinese state to substantially reduce its dollar holdings would cause a sharp fall in the US dollar. The Federal Reserve Board would be obliged to raise interest rates to exorbitant levels, both in order to attract the money necessary to keep the US government functioning and to defend the value of dollar. A hike in rates would then bring the US economy shuddering to a halt.

 

But it could be countered that such scenarios were unlikely because it was not in the interest of China to cause an economic crisis in the US, since this would bring its own export-led growth to an abrupt halt. As a political weapon, a sudden reduction in China’s dollar holdings was something of a nuclear option that could ensure the mutually assured economic destruction of all parties. Furthermore, it could be pointed out that from about 2005 China had already begun to rebalance its foreign exchange reserves by reducing the proportion held in the form of dollar denominated assets.12 But this rebalancing had necessarily been very gradual for fear of sparking a financial panic. If the market became convinced that the Chinese monetary authorities were to substantially reduce their dollar holdings, rather than merely accumulate them at a slightly slower rate, then speculators would rush to sell US government assets and US dollars triggering an economic crisis. Indeed, for the time being, it could be argued that the Chinese state was for all intents and purposes locked into the continued financing of US debts.

 

The mainstream view of bourgeois commentators and economists therefore considered such scenarios as being unlikely. However, if the mutually reinforcing dynamic of growth between China and the US was to break down it was generally accepted that this would be due the ‘financial imbalances’ arising from this dynamic causing a crisis in the foreign exchange markets resulting from a collapse in the exchange rate of the US dollar. But as we now know the crisis broke out in the global banking system not in the foreign exchange markets, or the market for US treasury bills - both of which remained remarkably stable given the scale of the financial crisis. The reason for this is that too much focus was placed on the accumulation of debt rather than on the wider impact of the financial flows that was giving rise to this stock of debt.

 

As we have seen, the demand for loanable capital from the global banking and financial markets to finance the rise of China had been limited. Yet, as we have now seen, China has provided a plentiful supply of short term loanable capital in the form of its purchase of US treasury bills. Short term money-capital that would have previously been invested in US treasury bills have been displaced into other financial markets. The supply of Chinese funds into the US Treasury Bill market has thereby served to swell the pool of loanable money-capital across all the global financial markets.

 

Yet this is not all. As we have seen, China’s rapid growth has pushed up world demand for primary commodities. This has meant the producers of such commodities have made major gains in trade and, as a result many have built up substantial trade surpluses. This is particularly the case for the oil exporting economies of the Middle East. The growing world demand for oil, largely driven by China, coupled with the decline of the old oil fields of the North Sea and Alaska, has led to the price of oil tripling in price between 2001 and 2007. With the lack of internal investment opportunities, other than the construction of super-luxury island resorts, and with much of the oil revenues flowing to the state, these windfall gains have taken the form of ‘sovereign wealth funds’. These funds have been set up to make investments abroad so as to secure future income for the Middle Eastern states when their oil eventually runs out. To a large but by no means exclusive part, these sovereign wealth funds have been used to buy up US and other government bonds, corporate bonds and equities and other financial assets traded on the global markets, as well as being deposited in western banks.

 

Thus the rise of China has both directly and indirectly contributed to the oversupply of loanable money-capital in the global financial system that can be seen to be the cause of the growing fragility and overexpansion of global banking and finance capital. Indeed, as Ben Bernanke, the current Chairman of the US Federal Reserve Board, has now with hindsight concluded:

 

In my view…it is impossible to understand this crisis without reference to the global imbalances in trade and capital flows that began in the latter half of the 1990s.13

 

But it was perhaps not only the sheer volume of loanable money-capital supplied by both China and the sovereign wealth funds that was important in contributing to the fragility of the financial system but also their nature. China’s purchase of foreign assets on the global financial markets was determined by the policy objective of controlling the rate of exchange of the Yuan to the US dollar; while the sovereign wealth fund’s was to make long term investments. Neither China nor the Middle Eastern governments were interested in making short term speculative profits. As such their investment flows were immune from the day to day shifts in market sentiment. They thereby provided financial markets with an important ballast against speculative volatility that contributed to the ‘great moderation’ and the complacency that it bred.

 

However, although Ben Bernanke may blame the Chinese, the international financial imbalances caused by the rise of China are only part of the story. We must now turn our attention back to the financial imbalances at the heart of the global accumulation of capital - that is the USA.

 

The over expansion of finance and the US economy – old and new

 

The US corporate ‘savings glut’


The dot.com crash brought the surge in investment in the US that had accompanied the emergence of the ‘new economy’ to an abrupt halt. As in any recession, companies realised that the growth projections in sales and profits which had justified high levels of investment during the heady days of the boom now looked decidedly shaky. If they were to avoid bankruptcy or hostile take-over bids, they had to abandon investment plans aimed at expanding their operations and instead set about cutting costs. Given that a substantial part of the surge in investment which had fuelled the boom had been financed by bank loans or the issue of shares or bonds on the financial markets, many companies found themselves in a precarious financial position. The first call on any profits they made had to be the paying down of debt and maintaining high dividend payouts to sustain shareholder value.

 

As we have previously pointed out, the recession that followed the dot.com crash proved to be particularly mild. After a brief period of retrenchment profit rates were soon restored. However, while profits made a quick recovery, investment in the real accumulation of capital proved to be far more protracted. Rather than re-investing the increase in their profits in expanding their business, companies continued to use it to pay down their debt, or in other ways improve their financial position.

 

This gave rise to a rather peculiar situation. Except for brief periods during an economic recession, the corporate sector as a whole would expect to be a net borrower. However, since the dot.com crash the US non-financial corporate sector has become a substantial net saver (see FT diagram). Indeed, it was a result of such prolonged net saving that much of corporate America found itself in an exceptionally strong financial position that allowed it to weather the credit crunch and the subsequent near meltdown of the global banking system so well. However, although they played an important part in insulating the ‘real economy’ from the impact of the financial crisis, the accumulated financial surpluses of the non-financial corporate sector can be seen to have played a significant role in causing the financial crisis in the first place. To understand this we must take a closer and disaggregated look at the net savings of the US corporate sector.

 

As we have seen, the global banking and financial system had played a major role in the take off of the ‘new economy’ in the 1990s. Most of the myriad of start up dot.coms had been financed by generous bank loans and share issues. No one, least of all bankers and investors, could predict which band of the computer geeks that turned up at the banks’ doors with a seemingly plausible business plan would prove to be the next Mircosoft. Many would never even break even. However, it was enough for just one to prove commercially viable and the returns could be astronomical. However, following the dot.com crash the structure and direction of development of the ‘new economy’ had begun to settle down. Mircrosoft, Google and Apple had become well-established major corporations, and the dot.coms that had survived the cull following the crash could stake out most of the available niches in the ‘new economy’. There was clearly less room for new entrants, and thus less need for starting capital. Those dot.coms that had survived the cull, were now up and running and making real, as opposed to prospective, profits. With the high rates of profit now being earned in the ‘new economy’, companies could fund most of their investment out of their own profits and had little need for external financing. The capital accumulation in the ‘new economy’ had taken off and its expansion had become more or less self-sustaining.

 

Thus, although the rate of investment in the ‘new economy’, unlike other parts of the economy, recovered rapidly after the dot.com boom, its demand for loanable money capital from the banks and the financial markets declined. However, in the ‘old economy’ the relation to the global banking and financial system was the reverse of that of the ‘new economy’. Whereas the ‘new economy’ had been a source of demand, the ‘old economy’ had been a source of supply of loanable funds.

 

As we have seen, the release of finance had imposed on the management of even the largest publicly quoted corporation, the overriding imperative to ‘maximise shareholder value’. To do this it was necessary to regularly distribute a large amount of profit the company made in the form of dividends to its shareholders. This meant that mangers were under pressure to increase profits or squeeze the amount of profit retained for re-investment into expanding the business. Failure to ensure high and regular returns on its shares would soon lead to investors selling their shares in order to buy other company’s shares that offered better returns. This would then soon lead to a sharp drop in the company’s share price, and hence to a fall in its stock market valuation. With its shares so cheap, the company would then be ripe for a hostile takeover bid and the old management would then face being replaced by a new management team willing to either force through the changes necessary to restore shareholder value, or else to oversee the whole or partial liquidation of the company through the sale of its assets. To the extent that they were not simply spent on consumption but reinvested on the financial markets, or deposited with banks, the increased dividends served to swell the supply of loanable money-capital flowing into the global banking and financial system.

 

However, from the late 1990s the imperative to ‘maximise shareholder value’, under the peril of hostile takeover bids, was intensified. In a period when loanable capital had been in relatively short supply, and when interest rates had been high, the main threat of a hostile takeover bid was from rival companies of at least a similar size, and operating in the same or a closely related industry. With loanable funds limited, any large scale takeover bid would find it difficult to raise enough funds to buy up sufficient shares to give overall control simply in cash. Instead any potential predator would have to offer to pay for shares, all or in part, with their own shares. This meant that any predator had to a corporation with a stock market valuation sufficiently large to swallow its prey. Furthermore, high interest rates meant that any takeover had to offer the prospects of substantial gains to make it worthwhile. The prospective gains from a takeover had to at least cover the interest on the funds borrowed, and be sufficient to offset any downward pressure in market valuation of the predator company due to the issuing of new shares to make the offer. Only rival firms could usually hope to make sufficient gains from any takeover through any synergies that could be obtained between the operations of the two firms, through the economies of scale that could be gained from merging the operations of two firms or by simply eliminating a close competitor. Simply appointing a more ruthless management team was, by itself, unlikely to be sufficient.

 

In a period of increasing abundance of loanable funds and low interest rates the number of potential predators is greatly increased by the feasibility of ‘leveraged buy outs’. Any consortium of well connected and wealthy businessmen could now launch a successful takeover of a large corporation through a ‘leveraged buy-out’. With an abundance of loanable funds, such a consortium need only advance a tenth, a twentieth or even as little as a thirtieth of the sum required to make a successful takeover bid of their own money, since they can easily borrow the rest. Furthermore, with interest rates so low, the new management team they hire to run the business need only make a marginal gain in the company’s stock market valuation before the consortium can sell the firm on, and with the proceeds pay off the loans they borrowed with interest and make a handsome return on the capital they themselves advanced.

 

In the rapidly expanding industries of the ‘new economy’ the best defence against hostile takeovers has been to reinvest rising profits in expanding the business to ensure the continued growth of profits in the near future. The prospect that investment in expanding the business now will soon lead to higher profits and thus higher dividend payments in the future should be sufficient to keep the stock market valuations high. However, in the ‘old economy’, which by any reasonable definition still comprises the bulk of the US economy, such a strategy is far less viable. Particularly for the old Fordist industries that have long since reached maturity, any investment in the real accumulation of capital is unlikely to bring quick returns. As such, any prospective profits from such investment are likely to be beyond the time horizon of most participants in the financial markets. They are therefore unlikely to carry much weight, however large they may be, on the stock market valuations.

 

As a result the primary response of companies and corporations in the ‘old economy’ to the threat of hostile takeovers has been to use the proceeds of rising profits to buy off the threat of hostile takeovers. Firstly, increased profits have been distributed in the form of higher dividend payments. Secondly increased profits have been used to pay down debt. Thirdly, in what has been a relatively novel defensive strategy that has been developed over the past decade, increased profits have been used to buy back the company’s own shares. As a result, a large part of the rising profits in the ‘old economy’ have flowed into the global banking and financial system in the form of free loanable money capital.

 

But like danegeld,14 buying off hostile attacks only serves to encourage the attackers to come back for more. By paying higher dividends, by paying down debt or by buying back shares, in order to ward off the danger that they themselves might face a hostile takeover, individual companies only serve to swell the supply of loanable money-capital that in general makes such attacks more likely. There has therefore been a degree of self perpetuation in the process that has seen both a growing supply of loanable money capital flowing into the banking and financial system and the slow recovery of investment into the real accumulation of capital in the US.

 

As we have seen, international financial imbalances, the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the continued liquidation of capital within the ‘old economy’ in the USA and other advanced capitalist economies, has resulted in an over-supply of free loanable money-capital. But before we can see how this oversupply of investable funds produced the recent financial crisis we must consider its impact in bringing about an over-accumulation of banking and finance, particularly in the USA.

 

 

The over accumulation of finance and banking


What has struck most observers of the emergence of the global finance and banking system over the past three decades has been the sheer speed of its expansion. This rapid growth has meant the growing relative importance of the financial sector. In the USA, where of course the heart of global finance and banking is located, the financial sector now accounts for around 20% of GDP. But, perhaps far more significantly, the financial sector accounts for around 40% of the profits made by US corporations. This means that the financial sector has been able to capture more than its fair share of profits, and this has been reflected in the above average rates of profits made by most banks and other financial institutions. How has the financial sector been able to sustain such rapid expansion and high levels of profitability?

 

Banking and finance as such does not produce surplus value directly. Financial profits arise from the appropriation of surplus value produced and realised in the production and circulation of commodities in the ‘real economy’. To this extent finance could be said to be parasitical on the real accumulation of capital. However, although the financial sector does not directly produce surplus value, it does play an important role in facilitating the process of capital accumulation. Thus, for example, the financial system is able to bring about substantial reductions in the costs of making monetary transaction. The provision of bank credit and overdraft facilities greatly reduces the need for capital to be held idle in the form of money reserves. And perhaps most importantly, the financial system serves to convert the small short term savings of the population into loanable money capital that can be used to support long term investment. By providing such savings and services to ‘real capitals’ banks and financial companies are able to extract a share of the surplus value they have produced in the form of commissions, fees and interest. However, while this may explain the basis on which banks and other financial companies derive their profits, it does not explain how the financial sector has been able to sustain such an exceptionally high profitability over the past few decades.

 

Now it is true as many critics of high finance maintain that the profitability of the financial sector has been boosted by its rather privileged position. Repeatedly over the past three decades the banks and other financial companies have been bailed out by governments after the bursting of speculative bubbles. From the ‘third world’ debt crisis of the early 1980s to the recent near meltdown of the global financial system following the collapse of Lehman Brothers, governments and monetary authorities have time after time been obliged to in effect ‘nationalise’ the losses of the financial system. What is more, the political power of the financial sector has led to the steady reduction in banking regulations that serve to limit the over expansion of finance and excessive risk taking that lead to speculative bubbles. As a result financial companies have been able to make more risky investments that promise big profits knowing that if things turn bad a large slice of the losses will be mopped up by the authorities. Furthermore, the financial sector can be seen to be under-taxed. Thus, for example, while companies involved the production and sale of commodities are usually subject to some form of sales tax such as VAT, financial transactions and services are usually exempt. More importantly the very mobility of finance allows the financial sector to avoid or evade tax, or make profits from helping corporations and individuals to do likewise.

 

It is no doubt true that bailouts and low taxes have contributed greatly to both the rapid expansion and the high profitability of the financial sector. However, we would argue the basis for such a sustained expansion and high profitability over the last thirty or so years has been the role the global financial system has played in bringing about the restructuring of global capital accumulation and the consequent restoration of profit rates. As we have seen, the development of global banking and finance has played an important role in the translocation of capital from industries and regions where profits are low and capital is over accumulated to new industries and regions where there is at least the prospect of high rates of profit. By mobilising loanable money capital to support the opening up of new areas of capital accumulation, by handling the vast increase in international money transactions this has entailed and by spreading and managing the risks of such speculative investments, the global banking and financial system has been able to take a significant cut in the increased profits that have resulted.

 

However we explain the rapid expansion and high profitability of the financial sector one further question remains: why has the rate of profit in the financial sector remained so high? Why hasn’t capital rushed into the financial sector to take advantage of the high profits that can be made there and thereby bring about a reduction in its rate of profit? There are formidable barriers to entry into large areas of the financial sector, particularly banking. To prevent any mountebank running away with other peoples’ money, there are strict legal requirements and restrictions on setting up banks and other similar institutions. The success of banks and other major financial companies depends on having specialist financial expertise, business connections and a long established reputation that cannot easily be reproduced by new entrants into the sector. As a result of such barriers most capital accumulation in the financial sector has been carried out by long-established banks and financial companies that have been able to sustain higher than average rates of profit.

 

Nevertheless there has been a rapid growth in small companies, such as hedge funds, that have been able to carve out distinct niches for themselves in the less regulated and more exotic parts of the financial system. But perhaps more importantly there has been, particularly over the past decade, a growing encroachment into the financial sector by large industrial and commercial corporations.

 

With the pressure exerted by financial markets to maximise shareholder value there has come what we term the ‘financialisation’ of industrial and commercial corporations. Such corporations are not so much in the business of producing or selling specific commodities but in making money. Under pressure to make quick returns the prospect of moving into aspects of finance has been attractive to many corporations that have large financial flows. Thus, for example, over the last ten years or so, many corporations have moved away from relying on overdrafts on their bank accounts to cover fluctuations in their cash flows. Instead they have issued ‘commercial paper’ – that is short term IOUs – that can be bought and sold on the financial markets. Although they may have to employ the services of an investment bank to manage the issue and redemption of such ‘commercial paper’, they save by being able to borrow at far lower interest rates than they would on an overdraft. They thereby take a cut of profits that would otherwise be made by their bank. However, some corporations have gone far further and opened up their own financial operations. General Motors for example moved from providing car loans to setting up its own mortgage company – GMAC – which ended up being bailed out after the bursting of the sub-prime mortgage bubble.15

 

Thus there has been a slow but significant encroachment of commercial and industrial corporations into the financial sector. By taking a slice of financial profits this encroachment has contributed to the downward pressure on profit margins in finance and banking. But this move into finance has not been due to a fall in the general rate of profit ruling in the industrial and commercial sectors of the economy, as orthodox Marxists might insist, which if anything have risen. On the contrary it has been due to the exceptionally high rates of profit that have arisen in the financial sector. Indeed, as we shall see, we might well conclude that it was not a low or falling rate of profit, but high though uneven rates of profits that have been the ‘ultimate cause’ of the crisis.

 

 

The over-supply of loanable money-capital and the causes of the recent crisis concluded


As we have argued, the emergence of global finance and banking has played a vital role in what Schumpeter would call the process of ‘creative destruction’ that resulted in the long economic upswing. In what may be described as the first phase of neoliberalism – that is from the late 1970s to the late 1980s – it had been the destructive side of this process that had been to the fore. The rise of global banking and finance played an important role in facilitating the neoliberal counter-offensive against the working class - providing the ‘economic imperatives’ necessary to roll back the gains of the post-war settlements. At the same time it liquidated capital fixed in the old Fordist industries in the advanced capitalist economies.

 

In what we may term the second phase – from the late 1980s to the late 1990s – the ‘creative’ side of this process from the point of view of capital became more prominent. Global banking and finance played an important role in facilitating the transfer of capital necessary for the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the ‘newly emerging market economies’ of Asia and elsewhere, which were to provide the basis for the long upswing.

 

However, in what we consider as the third phase – from the late 1990s up until the credit crunch of 2007 - the further development in the upswing was to have important implications for the character of global banking and finance. As we have seen, the rise of China, the take off of sustained capital accumulation of capital in the ‘new economy’ together with the continued liquidation of capital in the less profitable parts of the ‘old economy’ resulted in a situation where there was an increasing oversupply of loanable money capital.

 

The increasing abundance of loanable money-capital flowing through the global banking and financial system can be seen to have had two distinct consequences. Firstly, it produced a decline in financial volatility compared with the turbulence of the previous decade, since there was now plenty of loanable money-capital to go round the various spheres and areas of investment. This provided the basis of what was to be known as the ‘great moderation’ in financial markets following the dot.com crash.

 

Secondly, the abundance of loanable money-capital placed downward pressure on interest rates. This, together with increased competition due to overaccumulation of capital in the financial sector, depressed the profit margins of banks and other financial institutions.

 

In order to offset declining profit margins on their rate of profits, banks and other financial institutions sought to maximise the volume of their loans and other financial transactions. Encouraged by the complacency engendered by the ‘great moderation’, there was as a result a pressure to take on more risky loans and investments, as well as to reduce financial reserves to an absolute minimum. As a consequence, the global banking and financial system became increasingly overextended and fragile.

 

At first much of this oversupply of loanable money capital had been mitigated by the sharp increase in US government borrowing that had served to alleviate the impact of the dot.com crash. This had seen the US budget move from a surplus of 2% to a deficit of 4% of GDP in the first four years of Bush (jnr’s) term of office. However, after the re-election of Bush the US government budget deficit had stabilised and had begun to fall. Thus in the three years before the credit crunch there had been a rapid growth in the relative oversupply of loanable capital in the global banking and financial system. This was then further exacerbated by the attempt by the monetary authorities to raise interest rates which only served to invert the ‘yield curve’ and squeeze financial profit margins.

 

As a consequence, there was a frantic effort on the part of banks to expand loans and other financial transactions and ‘a search for yield’. The tendency towards the increasing fragility of the global banking and financial system was thereby greatly accelerated creating the conditions for the financial crisis of 2007-8 that we considered in detail in Part I of this article.

 

 

Conclusion

 

The financial crisis came to the rescue of ‘stagnationist’ radical and Marxist theorists, who up until then had been finding it increasingly difficult to explain away the continuation of the long economic upswing of the past two decades. Certainly it could be admitted that the almighty financial crash at the very heart of the system had finally happened. For the ‘upswingers’ the option seemed either to concur with most bourgeois commentators and conclude that the financial crisis was merely the result of some horrendous accident due to misguided monetary and regulatory policy, or rejoin the ‘stagnationist’ camp by claiming that the crisis marked the beginning of a long economic downswing.

 

Yet, as we have argued, there seems little to suggest we have entered a long downswing, or that capitalism is now mired in stagnation other than the financial crisis itself. Indeed the rapid recovery in profits, and the confidence of much of the bourgeoisie in the long term prospects of renewed capital accumulation, would seem to suggest otherwise.16 But if global capitalism is still in the middle of a long upswing, with historically high rates of profits, how are we to explain the unforeseen financial crisis of 2007-08?

 

As we have long argued, against the ‘stagnationist’ orthodoxy, ‘upswing’ theory has been correct in grasping that the restructuring of the global accumulation of capital that has occurred in the past decade, particularly the integration into the world economy of China and Asia, has led to the restoration of profit rates and, as a consequence, a sustained economic upswing. But as we now recognise, the problem is that the upswing theory has failed to adequately grasp the importance of the emergence of global banking and finance, and the role this has played in bringing about this restructuring.

 

Thus, in order to overcome the limitations of both the ‘stagnationist’ and ‘upswinger’ theories of the crisis it was necessary to examine the relation between the emergence and development of global banking and finance and the global restructuring of real capital accumulation that has occurred over the past thirty years. On the basis of this examination we have been able to conclude that the financial crisis of 2007-8 was caused neither by an accident due to misguided policy, nor a crisis in the financial system that simply reflected an underlying crisis of stagnation of the real accumulation of capital. But instead, the underlying cause of the financial crisis was an oversupply of loanable money-capital within the global banking and financial system that has arisen since the late 1990s. This in turn has been the result of developments in the real accumulation of capital - such as the rise of China, the take off of the ‘new economy’ and the continued liquidation of the ‘old economy’ - that have been central to sustaining the long upturn.

 

Hence, we might tentatively conclude that the nature and significance of the financial crisis is not that of a decisive turning point leading to an economic downturn or the end of neoliberalism as many have supposed, but more of a point of inflection pointing to a new phase in the long upturn.17 The significance of this new phase and the implications it has for the future development of global capitalism and the struggle against it is a question that we have no space to take up here.

 

  • 1. Originally we intended to begin Part II of this article with a critical review of the more salient Marxist and radical Keynesian theories of the current crisis. However, lack of space and time has meant that we decided to omit what could have easily become a rather lengthy academic exercise.
  •  
  • 2. Of course, the notion that capitalism is in decline has been a central tenet of traditional Marxism for the past hundred years (see ‘Theory of decline or the decline of theory’ in Aufheben #2, 3 and 4. But also see our self-critique of this article at http://libcom.org/aufheben/decadence ). As a result of the Great Depression, in the 1930s and 1940s such a notion was also shared by many bourgeois economic thinkers. Schumpeter, for example, in his Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy lamented the passing of the entrepreneurial spirit of nineteenth century capitalism and saw the evolution of capitalism towards a bureaucratic state socialism as almost inevitable. Keynes accepted Schumpeter’s prognosis, but, following John Stuart Mill, took a more sanguine view. Keynes looked forward to the time when capitalism would slow down and eventually reach a steady state in which vulgar money grabbing would no longer be necessary. His only concern was that capitalism would run out of steam before material scarcity could be abolished and wage-labour could be reduced to a minimum.
  •  
  • 3. Permanent Revolution are perhaps the most consistent vociferous proponents of the ‘upswing’ thesis. Also see our article on China in Aufheben #14.
  •  
  • 4. This failure to develop an adequate theory of the development of global banking and finance can also be traced back to the inadequacies of both Marx’s and Keynes’s theories of finance. Marx’s theory of money and finance is largely contained in Part V of Volume III of Capital. But this was cobbled together by Engels from various notebooks left by Marx after his death and remains very far from constituting a finished worked-out theory. It is true that Hilferding in his celebrated book Finance Capital attempted to develop and update Marx’s theory of money and finance. However, Hilferding’s theory is based on the particular concrete circumstance of Germany at the beginning of the twentieth century and hence its applicability to the analysis of modern global banking and finance is limited. More recently there has been some important work in attempting to develop systematically a Marxian theory of money and finance. See for example, The Political Economy of Money and Finance by Makoto Itoh and Costas Lapavitsas. However, this remains at too high a level of abstraction to be of much use in analysing the concrete circumstance of the recent financial crisis. Keynes was first and foremost a ‘monetary economist’. However, his primary aim, particularly in his seminal work The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, had been to persuade politicians and policymakers, who had been educated in neoclassical economic theory, to save capitalism through state intervention. To do this Keynes presented his theory as merely a generalisation of neoclassical monetary theory, which saw banks and financial markets as passive intermediaries between individual savers and individual entrepreneurs. Thus, although he made a number of observations and asides that go beyond the abstract conceptions of neoclassical monetary economics that have been taken up by his more radical disciples, the core of Keynes’s theory remains confined within bourgeois economic orthodoxy. As a result it has been relatively easy for mainstream bourgeois economic theory to re-assimilate Keynes’s theory as a special case that applies to the exceptional circumstances when the economy becomes stuck in a ‘sub-optimal equilibrium’.
  •  
  • 5. The crisis has certainly brought to the fore the writings of the rather idiosyncratic and neglected Keynesian economists H. Minsky. In short, Minsky argued that during a period of financial stability what he termed the financial structure of a capitalist economy would tend to become increasingly fragile. Continued financial stability encouraged the growth in confidence that loans would paid back. Reserves against bad loans would be reduced, financial innovations would be devised to get round existing regulations that aimed to ensure financial prudence and regulators would become complacent. Short term loans would be rolled over to finance long term investments and the as a result the financial structure would become increasingly speculative. As a result, eventually even a minor shock to the financial structure of the economy could cause a serious financial crisis. The crisis would then lead to renewed efforts at financial regulator and a return to financial prudence. This Minskyian financial cycle, in which financial stability produces financial instability, has been seized on by both mainstream and radical theorists to explain the recent financial crisis. Certainly at first sight it would appear to provide a neat explanation of how the sub-prime mortgage crisis served as a ‘Minsky moment’ that ended the ‘great moderation’. But on closer inspection the Minskyian explanation is not so neat after all. Firstly, Minsky’s notion of the ‘financial structure’ does not merely include banks and financial institutions but all economic actors such as businesses and individual households. Indeed this had been central for Minsky in order to show how a financial crisis such as the Wall Street crash could have such an impact on the real economy to create the Great Depression of the 1930s. But, as we shall, the great moderation which had preceded the credit crunch had seen non-financial corporate sector become more financially sound not less. Secondly, to the extent that it is taken to explain the recent financial crisis, the less it is able to explain the financial turbulence of the 1980s and 1990s when financial crises were far more frequent.
  •  
  • 6. From this perspective the crisis might be viewed like a tyre blow out in a Formula One race. But for the adept steering of the driver the crash could have been far more serious. Nevertheless the car as whole remains a functioning high performance vehicle. All that needs to be done is to fit a more suitable tyre and to remind the driver not to accelerate so fast out of a tight corner and all will be ok except for the minutes lost during the pit stop.
  •  
  • 7. See for example Fixing Global Finance by Martin Wolf and ‘Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis’, Paper presented to the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Asia Economic Policy Conference, October 2009, by M. Obstfeld and K. Rogoff.
  •  
  • 8. For an attempt to quantify the impact of international imbalances on US interest rates see ‘International capital Flows and U.S. Interest Rates’ F.E.Warnock & V.C. Warnock in Journal of International Money and Finance, 28 (6).
  •  
  • 9. The ‘yield curve’ relates the interest rates on government securities of increasing maturities. Given that the risk of governments major economies like the US, the US or Germany is considered negligible, the ‘yield curve’ indicates the relation between long and short term loans independent of variations in risk. Usually the yield curve is upward sloping: that is the longer the loan the higher the interest.
  •  
  • 10. Capital I p.236 Penguin edition. But as Engels notes on the same page ‘The monetary crisis, defined in the text as a particular phase of every general industrial and commercial crisis, must be clearly distinguished from the special sort of crisis, also called a monetary crisis, which may appear independently of the rest, and only affects industry and commerce by its backwash. The pivot of these crises is to be found in money capital, and their immediate sphere of impact is therefore banking, the stock exchange and finance’. Thus as Itoh and Lapavitsas have pointed out, there are two quite distinct types of financial crises. The first arising from the contradictions of real capital accumulation, the second arising from with the financial system itself. The financial crisis of 2007-8 would seem closer to the second type.
  •  
  • 11. ‘An Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods System’, NBER Working Paper Series, 2003, by M.P.Dooley, D. Folkerts-Landau and Peter Garber.
  •  
  • 12. Chinese monetary authorities were able to begin a gradual rebalancing of its foreign currency reserves for two reasons. Firstly, the opening up of other markets, particularly those in Europe, to Chinese exports meant that a larger proportion of export earnings in to China took the form of currencies other than the US dollar. Secondly, China allowed the a gradual but controlled appreciation of the Yuan against the US dollar.
  •  
  • 13. ‘Financial Reform to Address Systemic Risk’. Speech given by Ben Bernanke at the Council on Foreign Relations, Washington, D.C. March 2009.
    http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090310a.htm
  •  
  • 14. Danegeld (‘Dane's gold’ or Danish Tax) was a tax raised to pay tribute to Viking raiders to save a kingdom from being ravaged from 991 AD. However, once paid, it marked out those willing to pay as ‘easy marks’ – and the raiders would keep coming back demanding more.
  •  
  • 15. It can be argued that it was in part the decline in corporate deposits that obliged banks to increasingly fund mortgage lending by selling mortgage backed securities on the financial markets.
  •  
  • 16. Of course, the rapid recovery in profits following the crisis has yet to result in a surge in investment and thus real capital accumulation. Even if capital accumulation does take off the austerity measures imposed by governments across Europe is likely to mean economic recovery will be slow for several years.
  •  
  • 17. The crisis could be seen as an earthquake caused by the shifting tectonic plates of global capital accumulation as the centre of accumulation gradually shifts away from the USA and the old advanced capitalist economies towards China and Asia.
진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

What is a General Assembly?

  • 분류
    계급투쟁
  • 등록일
    2011/10/27 18:02
  • 수정일
    2011/10/27 18:02
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

대중총회란 무엇인가?

 

Introduction (ICC)

General Assemblies (GA) are the lifeblood of the struggle. This is where workers (from the private and public sectors, the unemployed, pensioners, students, children of working families etc.) can really take ownership of their struggles, decide collectively. This is the true place of workers' democracy. By being open to all, not limited by corporatism, the GA unites the various sectors of our class. It’s the place where the life of the struggle can be built and the struggles extended.

This is why unions concentrate all their efforts to sabotage them! The text below, produced by the CNT-AIT Gers ( http://sia32.lautre.net ) explains succinctly what a truly autonomous GA in the hands of strikers must be, and details the various pitfalls to guard against.


 

What is a general assembly? (Text of the CNT AIT, Gers)

Definition

We call a general assembly the regular meeting, democratic and sovereign, of workers, regrouped as and when, without criteria, which can be varied (those belonging to a union, a confederation of unions, a social movement). At no point should these workers be prevented from being delegates: the principle of the GA is the vote by head count.

Typology

There are several types of GA:

  • The GA of a single union
  • The combined GA of several unions
  • The GA of workers on strike

Moreover, it can be limited to a single profession or be ‘inter-professional’. [Regrouping those from many professions – trans.]

Functioning of the GA

  • The GA is democratic, and therefore guarantees each a turn to speak, shared equally in terms of duration and discussion topics. This is guaranteed by a mandate given to the moderator.
  • Speeches must also be consistent with an agenda, agreed at the beginning of the meeting, which does not include various decision points.
  • The GA is sovereign, and decisions are made by a show of hands, without any overturning of decisions, according to the agenda.
  • The GA meets regularly and keeps a record of its debates and decisions. The record is kept by a secretary appointed early in the meeting, who ensures the debates and decisions of the GA are made public. The GA gives the date and place of the next GA.

Threats to the GA

  • Monopolisation of debate: The GA becomes un-democratic. The classic case is the shop-steward who takes the role of moderator, participates in discussions or responds systematically giving their opinions. A variation on this is a participant in the room who monopolises the floor or speaks too often.
  • The handling of the debate: The agenda is not respected. When the debate is moving precisely towards direct action, or a motion to renew the strike, the agenda is changed in order to blur the clarity of discussion, and to confuse the whole point of a GA, which is to answer the question "What and how?"
  • Lack of democracy within the GA: the vote is not respected. Violating the agenda, votes are taken several times on decisions already made. Often, manipulation occurs at the end of the meeting, to destroy its coherence and audacity.
  • Neutralisation of the GA: there is no alternative to a GA, however rich. Often, a GA of striking workers is treated as a safety-valve for their anger, neutralising their revolt, transforming their militancy into a sterile talking-shop. Be on guard! In a GA, we have all the tools at hand to see if they are being monopolised, manipulated, and neutralised. In all cases, failure to denounce the above threats will undermine our activity, our words, and our decisions: in short, our very reason to go on strike!

"The emancipation of the workers will be the task of the workers themselves"

SIA 32 (Member of the CNT-AIT).

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

혁명을 거역하는 노동조합

혁명을 거역하는 노동조합

                                           - G.무니스

 

 

Unions against revolution - G. Munis

 

 

 경제적인 면과 정치적인 면 두 가지 사이에 가장 명료하게 유기적, 기능적인 구분을 가정한다고 할지라도, 그 둘 사이에 모순이란 존재할 수 없다. 어떠한 반동적인 개념이라 할지라도 이것은 사실이다. 따라서 오늘날, 경제적 조직인 노동조합과 이데올로기 기구인 정치적 정당사이의 상호소통, 동의와 협력은 한쪽이 다른 한쪽을 그리고 다른 한쪽이 그 한쪽을  중요하게 생각하는 두 가지 모두를 이해하는데 중요한 열쇠를 제공한다. 이러한 진술은 수천 년의 경험을 통해서 인간에 의해 검증되고, 이성에 의해 증명된다기보다는 오래된, 변하지 않는 원칙으로부터 나온다. : 모든 관념이나 정치적 행동은 경제적 기반으로부터 나오는데 이는 통제하고 결정짓는 역할을 한다. 이러한 작업의 과정에서 , 다른 측면에서, 우리는 정치학과 경제학 사이의 상호침투를 시험 할 것이며, 노동조합이 현재에 어떻게 기능하고 있는 지를 살펴봄으로써 노조를 평가할 것이다.

 

 노동계급의 방어적인 조직으로써 처음 나타났던 노조들은 인간이하의 노동환경에 직면했고, 오래된 친목단체나 회사의 확장으로써의 산업적 측면에서 그들 자신을 드러내고 있다.  노조는 그들의 열망에 기반 해서 개량주의 수준에까지도 도달하지 않고 있다.  이데올로기적이며 경제적인 분석을 이용하자면, 개량주의는 혁명적인 행동에 대한 요구 없이 법적인 발전을 통해서, 자본주의적 민주주의 방식으로 사회주의를 달성하는 것이 가능하다는 것을 주장한다. 조합들에게는 발전이냐 혁명이냐에 대한 물음은 전혀 없었으며 더군다나 사회주의에 대한 물음조차 없었다. 노조는 착취당하는 노동자들을 위해서, 좀 더 참을만하고 덜 굴욕적인 노동환경을 얻으려 하는 것이 아니라, 시간이 증명해왔듯이, 자본에 좀더 적합한 노동환경을 얻으려는 시도에서 더 나아가지 않는다. 이러한 한계에도 불구하고 초기의 노조들은, 혁명가가 아니라면, 적어도 노동계급의식을 가지며 오늘날의 노조들의 왜곡된 계급의식, 타락과는 대비되는 건전한 구성을 가진 조직이었다.

 

 19세기 후반, 20세기 초반에 소위 혁명적 조합주의(생디칼리즘)가 나타났다. 이는 상황에 맞는 취사선택 이론이었으며 , 맑시스트 개념으로부터 나온 소위 무정부주의적 정치주의와 오래된 노동조합부터 만들어진 엄격한 경제적 주장을 압도한다. 가장 위대한 흐름의 시기와 이러한 형태의 조합주의의 공세가 개량주의의 정점과 함께 나타났다는 사실에 역설은 없다.

 

 소렐과 베른슈타인은 동시대인인데다가, 차이점보다 공통점을 더 많이 가지고 있었다. 소렐이 생디칼리즘에서 역사적 문제에 대한 해결책을 제안하는 데 반해, 베른슈타인과 그의 경향은 의회주의 안에서, 심지어 자본축적의 필요성 안에서 사회주의 사회에 대항하는 확실하고 조화로운 발전의 행복한 기계장치를 추구했다. 실제로 혁명적인 생디카리즘과 개량주의는 부르주아계급의  무서운 경제적 욕망과 관계있다는 점에서 같았다. 그 기간 안에 부르주아지는 그들의 개화가능성의 절정과 엄청난 크기의 자유의 부여, 좌파에 기대는 (그들의 이상적-경제적 관념으로부터 완전히 벗어나지 못한)사람들에 대한 환상을 달성하였다. 이러한 이유로 1914년의 정치적 파산은 생디칼리스트들, 개량주의자들과 함께 진행될 수 있었다. 비록 스페인의 군사적 중립이 프랑수의 C.G.T. 의 항복의 문서와 자세에 대해 자비를 베풀었지만 스페인의 C.N.T 조차 예외가 아니었다. ; 뒤에서 살펴보겠지만, 그것의 파산은 1936년과 1939년 사이에 프롤레타리아 혁명의 시기에 일어났다.

 

 노동조합의 수치적인 증가와 사회적 힘은 1914년 이후 계속적으로 증가했으며, 프랑스와 같은 몇몇 나라에서는 만약 그들의 수치로 인한 힘이 지난 몇 년간 심각하게 줄어들었다면 그들의 중요성은 점차로 커져왔다. 노동조합들에게 1914년의 참사는 그들 자신의 것으로 들어가는데 있어서 필요한 사건이었다고 이야기 되어져왔다. 이것은 그때까지 자본주의가 노조를 파괴적인 힘으로 두려워했고 노조가 할 수 있는 협력적인 역할을(아마도 영국을 제외하고는)보여주지 않았기 때문이다. 그러나 1차 세계대전 이후로 공장에서의 “노동자들의 지배”라는 수많은 경험들은 자본가들이 만족할만한 효과에 의해 그들을 만족시켜왔다. “노동자들의 지배”는 자본에 대한 노동자들의  투쟁을 약화시켜왔고, 공장의 공정과정을 촉진시키고 있으며 무엇보다도 산출을 증가시키고 있다. 노동조합들은 (특별히 자본주의적인 총체인)조국의 방어자로서 뿐만 아니라 착취의 구조 그 자체 안에서의 효과적인 부역자로서 눈에 띄었다. 그것은 그들의 부를 만들었고 그들에 대한 의심되지 않는 지평으로서 열렸다.(?) 그러나 이는 노조가 그들의 결정적인 방향을 정했던 국제노동운동사안에서의 (여러 가지 이유로)매우 중요한 기점이었던 1936년과 1937년 사이의 일 이었다. 이 기간 동안 그들은 그들이 자본주의 사회의 가장 굳건한 기둥의 하나가 되어가는 데 대해 고마워하는 성질을 보여주었다.

 

 20년의 시간이 러시아와 스페인의 혁명을 분리 시켰고, 이는 자본주의에 대항한 세계 프롤레타리아의 공격의 폭발의 처음이자 마지막이었고, 많은 나라 안에서의 부단한 공격에 의해 주목받는 공격이었다. 스탈린 관료주의가 국가자본주의의 건설을 완성하고 스페인 혁명이 최고조로 달한 그 순간, 스탈린주의자들은 모든 진정한 공산주의자들을 총과  온갖 중상모략, 비방을 통해 제거했다. 이것은 계급투쟁의 조직적인 요소들과 타락한 모든 이데올로기적 요소들을 결정적인 방법으로 변화시키기 위한 것이었다. 오랜 시간 동안 국제적인 노동운동에 대한 러시아의 간섭은 부정적인 것이었다. ; 스페인에서 ‘러시아지배 공산당’은 그 자신의 보존의 요구에 의해 질질 끌려 다녔고, 이는 원칙적으로 반혁명적인 경찰력이었음이 밝혀졌다.  1936년 7월, 대부분의 나라에서 군대를 파괴하려는 프롤레타리아의 반란을 방해하려는 시도는 (다행히도) 헛되이 끝났다. 1937년 5월 공산당은 프롤레타리아를 기관총으로 쏘려했는데 프롤레타이라는 C.P.의 반동적인 경찰에 대항해 반항하고 있었으며, 그것을 물리치고 무장해제 시켰으며 혁명을 부숴버렸다.  1936년에 군대가 하려다가 실패한 것을 스탈린주의는 10개월 후 이룩하였다.

 

 처음에 모스크바는 그자신의 영역에서 벗어나 반혁명적인 힘으로서 직접적으로 행동했다. 현재까지 이사건의 엄청난 반동적인 결과에 대한 진정한 비판은 없었다. 그러나 이것은 다음에서 이야기하는 세계의 중요한 모든 행동들의 원천이었다 : 히틀러-스탈린 협정과 두 번째의 “위대한 전쟁”으로부터 “평화로운 공존”의 정책과 독일, 폴란드, 헝가리에서와 같은 반란까지. 후자는 1937년 5월의 스페인 프롤레타리아의 혁명과 같은 수준에서 일어난 것이 아니라 1936년 7월 폭동과 거의 같은 수준에서 일어난 것이었는데 이는 프랑코의 군대 안에서 스탈린의 군대와 경찰이 함께 했다. 헝가리에서의 Imre Nagy와 그의 동료들은 1936년 스페인의 ‘대중 전선’과 같았다. : 혁명적인 격변기의 부산물이지만 혁명의 핵심은 아니었다.

 

 노조가 자본의 보조적 기관으로서 그들을 명백히 했던 잠재적 특성을 드러냈던 1936년 즈음은 중요하다. 그 과정에서 그 자신을 위해서 (영국과 미국의 노조의 예를 제외하고)노조 안에서 큰 흐름을 성취해낸 것이 스탈린주의라는 것은 당연하다. 자본주의의 경제적 경험론은 러시아의 반혁명적 경험주의 안에서 보다 높은 정치적 표현을 찾아냈으며 그것을 고무시켰고 동시에 완벽하게 했다.  이들 두 가지 요소는 좀 더 나은 사회적 환경을 창조하기 위해서 섞이고 병합되었다.  현재 이러한 환경은 다소간 완결된 형태로 존재한다. : 현 상태에서 “후퇴한” 나라를 포함하여 각각의 국가를 따져 봤을 때 이것은 독립된 하나의 경우가 아닌 세계체제전체의 일부분으로서 그것은 자본주의 이상은 아무것도 아니다.

 

 우리는 파업할 권리에 대하여 좀 더 굳건하다고 자부하며, 그 자신의 민주주의에 대하여 자부심을 가진 서구를 살펴볼 것이다. 실상 이러한 권리는 노동자들에게 주어진 것이 아니라 법에 의해서 그들의 대표, 즉 노조가 가진 것으로 인식된다. 노동자 자신들에 의해 일어나는 파업은 그것을 파괴하려는 노조나 국가와의 제휴를 맞이하게 된다- 종종 노동자들의 직접적 패배에 의해서 혹은 노동자들에게 중재안을 받아들이게 함으로써. 1936년의 프랑스의 혁명적 파업이 공산당(토레즈:“누군가는 파업을 끝내는 법을 알아야한다.”)과 사회주의 정당(Blum 정부와 경찰은 “사회주의자들”에 의해 명령받았다.)에 의해(파업이 그들의 정치경제적 이해에 반대하기 때문에) 실패한 이후로, 거의 모든 나라는 파업이 노조에 의해 실패한다는 것을 알고 있다. 그러므로 실제적으로, 그리고 법적으로 파업은 노조에게 위임된다. 그러나 그것이 전부가 아니다.  항상 파업이라는 예외적 상황을 넘어서, 계급투쟁이 꾸준히 만들어지고 있는 - 자본과 노동의 일상적 관계 안에서 노조는 둘 사이의 완충장치로서만 역할을 하는 것이 아니라 자본으로부터 노동자로의 메신저로서의, 노동자를 자본의 요구에 적응시키는 것을 돕는 앞잡이로서 나타난다. 노조에 의해 독점되어버린, 자본에 대한 노동의 모든 투쟁의 표현은 자본의 이익을 위해 노동자들에게 등을 돌린다.

 

 우리는 위에서 한 논증의 말들이 부인할 수 없는 확고한 사실이라는 것만을 상기해야만 한다. 공장위원회 뿐 만 아니라 매장, 상점 혹은 직업적 영역의 대표들은 국가에 의존하고 있다면 그들의 선출방식이 선거라 할지라도 노동자들의 자유의지의 표현이 아니다. 그들은 노조를 대표하고 있을 뿐이다. 그 안에서 노동자들은 그들이 원하는 누군가를 선출하는데 자유롭지 못하다. : 유명한 영국 상점의 지배인들이 산별노조의 동의를 원한다 할지라도. 대부분의 나라에서 법적으로 노조는 노동계급을 대표한다고 규정하고 있다. 그러므로 노동자들은 더 이상 자신들이 그들 자신들을 대표할 권리를 가지고 있지 못하며, 국가나 고용주들과의 협상을 하기위해, 그들의 투쟁을 지도하기 위해 노조 아닌 다른 기관을 만들 권리는 더더군다나 없다. 노동계급의 권리와 노조의 권리는 명백하게 둘로 나뉘며 상호 모순적이다.  이 때문에 노동자들과 공장위원회, 상점대표사이의 대립-잠재적인 형태로 늘 상 존재하는 대립-은 고용주와의 대립이 있을 때마다 첨예해지고 투쟁이 광범위해지면 직접적인 대립으로 변한다. 지난 20년간 이름 있을 만한 모든 파업은 노조의 의지에 반하고 공장안에서의 대표자들을 포위해야만 했다. : 노동자들 자신들은 파업위원회를 선출해야만 했다. 그러나 노동자들에 의해 선출된 공장위원회나 파업위원회는 매번 노조지도자들에 의해 그들 스스로 설득당하도록 허락했고 자본은 우위를 점했다.

 

 단체 노동협약의 목적은 다양한 영역에서 고용주의 횡포를 제한하는 것이었다. : 노동조건과 근무시간, 착취의 강도(시간당 생산성), 범주에 따른 임금범위(상하관계), 고용과 해고, 정치적 권리, 발언의 자유와 공장안에서의 위원회, 공장규정 등등. 그러나 (법 아래에서 유일하게 협상하고 그것에 서명할 수 있는)노조의 손안에서의 단체협약은 보통 자본에 대한, 특이하게는 노조에 대한 프롤레타리아의 종속을 위한 무서운 제도가 되었다. 사실, 현재 노조는 부분적으로 혹은 종합적으로 착취의 대리인이 되었다. 사실 클로즈드 샵(조합원만을 고용하는 사업소)의 경우를 제외하고 해고와 고용은 거의 자본의 자비에 위임되어있으며 이것은 노동자들의 보증된 노동과는 거리가 먼 것으로 단순하게 말해서 노조에게 파산의 권리를 준 것이다. 이것은 우리가 아래 글에서 동구의 노조에 대해 이야기할 때 보게 될 최악의 종류의 반동적인 경제적 탄압이다.

 

 노동계약은 임금의 차이와 노동자들 간의 범주적 ,기술적 기능과 관련된 적대감 때문에 노동계급의 서로 반대되는 그룹으로의 위계적 분화를 찬성하고 장려한다. 노조는 프롤레타리아가 자본에 대한 작은 블록을 형성할 때를 제외하고는, 그들의 본성 때문에, 본능적으로 위계적 기초에 의한 프롤레타리아의 분화를 돕는다. 위계적인 노동관계를 통한 프롤레타리아의 분화의 필요성과 그로인한 최상위층의 이해로부터의  소외의 필요성은 자본만큼이나 노조에게도 중요한 것이다. 한 세기 동안 노동운동은 그 자신안의 위계적 관계에 대항하여 싸워왔고, 넓은 영역에서 그 물적 기반을 제한하면서 위계질서에 찬성하는 편견을 깨부쉈다. 지난 몇 십년동안 노조와 그들의 정치적 격려자들은 폭넓게 위계적 적대감을 재구축하고 노동 영역의 숫자를 늘리는 데 성공하였다. 오늘날 대부분의 노동자들은 위계적 노동관계가 자연스럽거나 “정당”하다고 생각한다.

 단체 협약의 본래적 이상이, 자본이 완전한 억압을 기대하는 동안 그것의 전횡을 억제하는 것이었다면, 오늘날 그들은 자본주의의 기능적 요구에 부합하는 자본주의 시스템을 통제하는 거의 완벽한 방법을 구성한다. 단체협약에서 협상과 서명을 하는데 노조는 생산수단을 독점한 그룹의 필수적인 일부처럼 행동한다. 미국과 다른 나라에서 많은 수의 노조는 회사 안에서 그들의 구성원을 착취하는 중요한 주주이다. : 이는 사회주의에 대한 기대와는 거리가 먼 것으로 가장 큰 경제적, 이데올로기적 개념 안에서 노조를 착취의 수익자로 변화시키는 것이다. 노조들은 노동자들에 대한 착취의 계획을 끌어내는데 실제적으로 참여하지 않는 곳에서 이러한 권리를 찾는다.

 

 계급투쟁의 현장인 작업장, 특히 큰 공장은 가장 혁명적인 노동자들에게 영구적이며 원대한 실질적, 이데올로기적 활동을 줄 수 있다. 그러나 이러한 활동이 노조에 의해 만들어지는 것은 불가능하다. 빈번하게 단체협약은 어떤 노동계급의 활동에 서 필수불가결한 모임과 토론뿐만 아니라 공장안에서의 정치적 선전과 활동을 금지할 것을 규정한다. 여러 해 동안 노조는 고용주들과 함께 음모를 꾸며왔는데, 그때마다 혁명적인 노동자들을 축출하는 문제가 있었다. 이러한 해고는 현재 단체협약의 조항으로 합법화되거나 은밀히 인정되었는데 왜냐하면 이러한 조항은 모든 공장에서 고용주들에 의해 만들어진 법에 의해 만들어져있기 때문이다. 노조와 그들의 정치적 고무자들은 혁명적 전단을 살포하는 사람들에 대항하여 그들을 진압할 필요가 있다면 경찰로써 행동하는 임무를 맡아왔다. 이탈리아에서 스탈린주의 노조의 지도자들은 고용주들에게 경고 없이 혹은 보상 없이 전단지나 어떤 형태의 선동문구를 살포하는 죄가 있는 노동자들을 해고할 수 있는 권리를 주었다. 프랑스에서, 대부분의 공장법규는 노동자들의 생각을 제한할 수 있는 것을 허용하는 것만큼 대부분의 반항적인 노동자들이 그들 스스로를 표현하게 하는 것을 제한하게 하여 그들을 조용하게 했다. 독일, 영국, 미국에서의 상황역시 러시아나 스페인에서의 상황 이상으로 좋지 않았다. 그러므로 자본과 노조기구의 집중성 있는 행동에 감사하면서, 노동계급은 스스로 작업장에서조차 비밀스러운 행동을 줄였으며 작업장은 학대받고 착취 받는 공간이 되었다.

 

 프롤레타리아는 그들의 정치적 자유를 회복해야만 한다. 그 자유는 현재의 고용주-노조라는 법적 테두리를 벗어던지지 않고서는 불가능하다. 노동의 실제적인 측면을 존경하는 사람들의 완전한 자유는 처음부터 미래의 혁명적인 민주주의와 공산주의를 포함한다. 오늘날 스스로를 공산주의자라고 부르는 사람들이 전혀 공산주의자가 아니고,  그들에 대한 정통성 있는 반감을 통해 진정한 공산주의자가 종종 공산주의를 주장하는 것을 피하기 때문에 우리는 공산주의를 말하고 있는 것이다.

 

 엄밀하게 경제적 영역 안에서 노동계급의 상황은 결코 오늘날의 것보다 나쁘지 않았다. 4시간 혹은 5시간 노동에 의해 오래전에 바뀌었어야 하는 8시간 노동은 현재 종이위에만 존재한다. 많은 나라에서 기준시간 이상의 과다노동에 대한 거부는 곧바로 해고로 직결된다. 심사숙고하여 낮게 유지되고 있었던, 생산성 등에 기초한 소위 “기본급(러시아어로 norm)”과 보상금, 보너스는 노동자들에게 하루 10시간에서 12시간까지 일하는 것을 수용하게 강요할 뿐 아니라 가장 나쁜 노동(성과급이라는) 모든 형태의 노동조건을 새롭게 강요함으로써 사실상 일당, 시급을 폐지하였다. 이러한 발단이래로 노동운동은 가장 오래된 모든 형태의 이러한 착취를 끝내는데 노력해왔는데 이러한 착취는 노동자들을 육체적으로 지치게 하고 지적으로 우매하게 만든다.

 

  유럽 대부분에서 이러한 성과급방식의 노동을 제거하는데 성공했다. 20년 전만해도 대부분의 노동자들은 어떤 종류의 성과급을 받아들이는 것이 품위를 손상시키는 것이라고 생각했다. 그러나 오늘날 성과급은 자본이 이를 강요했기 때문이라기보다 노조에 의한 사기극을 통해서 다시 규칙이 되었다. : 사실 이 부분에서 우리는 노조와 자본의 궁극적 친화성을 확인한다. 시간당, 개인당 생산성이라는 착취의 가장 깊은 면에 대하여 유념할 때 프롤레타리아는 끔직한 상황으로 그 자신이 강요받는 것을 발견한다. 그것으로부터 산출되는 생산성은 매일 엄청난 비율로 증가한다. 먼저, 기술적 혁신은 노동자들을 그들의 노동에 대한 어떠한 창조적인 개입으로부터 분리해내고 그의 움직임을 부차적이 것으로 측정하며 노동자들을 기계의 리듬에 맞게 종속된 살아있는 로봇이 되게 한다. 그다음, 흉악하고 불쾌한 올가미는 사람들을 동일한 도구로 동일한 시간동안 끝없이 일하게 강요한다. 마지막으로 각각의 기업에서의 훈련은 대변을 보거나 담뱃불을 붙이는 것과 같이 일에 대한 가장 작은 소홀함조차 감소시킨다. 이러한 방법으로 각각의 개인으로부터 산출된 생산물은 막대한 것이며, 따라서 같은 비율의 노동자의 정신적, 육체적 소모이다.

 

 이러한 문제를 언급한다는 것은 누군가의 손가락을 현대사회와 그 일부분인 노조의 사악함 위에 놓는 것이다. 또한 이러한 문제는 생산과 분배사이의 현재적 관계를 벗어버리지 않고서는, 간단히 말해 혁명을 만들지 않고서는 해결할 방법이 없다. 그러나 이 의문점을 정확하게 다루기 위해서는 무엇보다 동구권전체의 모델인 러시아에서 노조가 무엇을 나타내는가와 그것을 넘어선 많은 나라에서 조차 무엇을 흉내 내야만 했는지를 봐야만 한다.

 

 서구에서의 노조의 반동적인 일과 프롤레타리아 상황의 악화에 대하여 언급되어온 모든 것들은 러시아 세계에 대해서는 더욱 사실이다. 스탈린의 방패아래서 러시아의 국가 자본주의가 설립된 이래로 예전의 모든 부르주아 세계는 그것으로부터 착취에 대한 교육을 받았다. 이것들은 경찰진압과도 관련이 있다. 그러나 여기에서 우리는 노동과 자본사이의 특별한 관계와 노조의 역할에 대해서 이야기 하는 것으로 우리스스로를 한정시킬 것이다. 이와 같이, 만약 일반적으로 모든 곳에서 오랫동안 ,노조가 노동 계급 안에서 자본의 보조적인 힘이었다면, 노조에게 매우강한 힘을 주고 그들에게 매혹적인 예를 제공함으로써 스탈린주의의 반혁명은 노조의 본질적 운명을 폭로해왔다. 1936년 이후로 서구에서의 프롤레타리아에 대한 착취를 약화시키고 그것의 구체화를 강화하는 거의 모든 수단은 스탈린주의 러시아 안에서 그 모델을 찾았다.

 

 정치적 권리와 공장 안팎에서 모임을 개최할 권리에 대한 완전한 억압 ; 고용주에 의해 강요된 초과노동이나 공식적 노동에 대한 부적합한 기본급(norm) ; 고용주의 결정에 따른 징계수단이나 벌금, 고용주는 또한 공장 법규를 명령한다. ; 시간동작연구와 무수히 많은 통제, 일한 분량에 따라 임금이 지급되는 노동, 기술적 “자격”과 임금에 기초한 프롤레타리아 내에서의 위계적 분화 ; 오직 자본에게만 이익이 되는 단체협약, 생산자들의 손해로 향하는 끝없는 생산성의 증가, 법에 의한 혹은 실제적인 파업금지 ; 짧게 말해, 서구에서 노조조직을 점점 더 부정적인 조직으로 이행하게 하는 모든 것은 1930년대 러시아로부터 강한 자극을 받았고, 전 세계적으로 자본과 노조에게 영향을 주었다.

 

 적어도 러시아의 상황을 알고 있는 사람들에 의해서 만이라도 잘 알려져 있는 것은 , 기득권층과 피착취계층 사이의 경제적 불평등은 다른 범주간의 노동자들의  질적 차이처럼 다른 곳의 불평등보다 더욱 컸다. 자본주의의 원인이자 동시에 효과인 기득권층과 피착취계층 사이의 불평등은, 그것이 노조의 전망과 발전에 영향을 줄때에만 우리와 관계된다. 다른 나라에서와 마찬가지로 러시아에서 이러한 불평등이 노동자들에 의한 자본의 몰수에 대한 필요성을 높이며, 이는 모든 법체계와 공식적 정당을 포함한 현재의 국가 기관을 완전히 파괴하는 반란이 아니고서는 불가능하다. 이러한 순간에 대한 언급은 충분하다.

 

 다른 어떤 부르주아지보다도 스탈린식 관료주의는 노동 주기의 가속화와 가능한 한 최대한의 직업분류로 프롤레타리아를 인도하는 것에 의해 착취를 증대하는 방법을 안다. 생산을 “촉진”하는 전통적인 자본주의의 방식은 프롤레타리아의 역사적 이윤의 동질성을 이질적인 즉각적 이윤의 다양성으로 치환시키는데 이는 일반적 혁명 활동을 방해하는 수많은 장애물인 것이다. 한 번 더 말하자며, 러시아 노조와 정치적 “장애물”은 그들의 서구식 상대방을 제압했다. 러시아에서 노동자 우두머리는 노동을 하고 있는 그들의 동료에 대한 착취로부터 가장 무시무시한 이익을 얻는다. : 스타하노프주의자들은 “기본급”을 능가하며 그들의 팀 안의 노동자들의 숫자 비율에 따른 보너스를 받았다. 그러므로 그들은 그들의 임금이 보통 노동자들에 대한 착취로부터 증대되는 것을 보며 그러므로 이 착취를 증가시키게 된다. 스타하노프주의자들은 그러므로, (임금이 고정된) 서구의 우두머리들 보다 더 분명하게, 노동에서 그들의 동료들의 적으로 변한다.

 

 러시아에서의 모든 것은 그것의 반대로 변했기 때문에 이 모든 것에서 놀랄 것은 없다. 한때 혁명이 자본주의 독재국가인  반혁명에게 길을 내어주었을 때, 그 반혁명은 스스로를 선동적으로 프롤레타리아 독재라고 칭하며 사회주의자로써 가장 부패된 모습과 전통적 자본주의의 원칙을 보여 준다-실제로는 강요한다.1939년 통과된 노동법은 말한다. : 자본주의 국가 안에서의 임금을 특징화시키는 기본적 특징은 전문노동자와 비전문노동자사이의 임금에 서열화하는 것이다. 노동에 대한 보수로써 소부르주아의 서열화는 사회주의의 가장 큰 적이다. 수년 동안 마르크스주의-레닌주의는 그치지 않고 서열화와 싸웠다. 

 

 수년 동안 스탈린주의자들은 맑스 사상의 충실한 표현으로써 임금노동을 통한 산업발전을 제시함으로써 사람들을 끌어들이려 노력했다. 반대로 맑시즘은 임금노동의 폐지와 사회의 경제적 서열화의 폐지, 모든 개인적 요구의 무제한적 만족의 폐지, 개인적 집단적 만족에 필수불가결한 위대한 자유의 폐지를 확립했다. 우리가 만약 그것을 향하고 있지 않다면 , 혁명적인 어떤 것도 현재의 역사적 고비에 실현될 수 없다. 오래된 자본주의 국가에서 프롤레타리아 안에서의 임금차이는  자본과 노동사이의 직접시장관계에 의해 성립된 조건이다. 러시아에서 이러한 임금격차는 헌법에 의해, 원칙이라는 상태를 확보했으며 결국 이것에 대한 투쟁은 범죄가 된다. 부르주아가 ‘재산권’(사실상 재산은 우리가 재산이라고 생각할 때 그것과 반대로 밝혀지는데 노동의 도구나 생산의 수단이 아니라 물질적 소비와 각각의 인간들의 정신적 발전에 필요한 모든 것이다.) 이라는 거룩한 핑계를 통한 경우가 아니면 절대로 인간 대 인간의 사회적 관계로 인정하지 않는 자본과 노동사이의 전통적 관계는, 러시아에서, 다른 능력을 가진 사람들 사이의 자연스럽고 잠재된 관계로 전이된다. 그러므로 사회적 계급이나 한계가 있는 범주대신에 우리는 재능이나 특별한 기능에 기반 한 법에 의하여 한정된 계급을 가지고 있는 것이다. 그럼에도 불구하고 사실, 부에 기반 한 한정은 그것을 잃어버리는 것 대신에 중요한 것이고, 보다 나쁜 것은 인간에 의한 인간의 착취에 대한 생물학적 정당화의 기미가 있다는 것이다. 

 

Grandizo Munis (스페인) 

1912-1989

처음엔 볼셰비키-레닌주의자( Bolshevik-Leninista)였지만 이후  스페인의 좌익 반대파가 되었고, 나중엔 트로츠키의 아내  Natalia Sedova와 함께 좌익공산주의자가 되었습니다. 
이후 그는 좌익공산주의 역사에서도 소개되는 Fermento Obrera Revolucionario (FOR)그룹을 주도합니다.

 

-무니스의 저서로는

  The Bourgeois State in Crisis, 5 April 1937

  The Road to Victory Begins with the Revolutionary Front of the Proletariat, 5 April 1937

  The Bolshevik-Leninists of Spain Demand Your Aid in the Struggle for the Social Revolution, 29 May 1937

  The Programme of the Spanish Bolshevik-Leninists, September 1937

  Spain One Year After Franco's Victory, August 1940

  Franco’s Dilemma, February 1941

  Who Are Hitler’s Agents in Russia?, November 1941

  Observations on the Guerrillas, March 1944

  The Future of the Soviet Union And The Victories of the Red Army, October 1944

  A Correction, March 1945

  Defense of the Soviet Union and Revolutionary Tactics, March 1945  

    

                                                                                                                                                                                                           

Unions against revolution - G. Munis

 

A critique of trade and syndicalist unions from a communist perspective by G. Munis.

 

No contradiction can exist between the economic and the political aspects of a revolutionary conception, even supposing the clearest organic and functional demarcation between them. The same is true for any reactionary conception. Hence the present inter-penetration, the agreement and collaboration between unions - economic organs - and political parties - ideological organs - gives us the key to understanding both, from whichever side one looks at the matter. This statement proceeds from an old and unalterable principle, more than proven by reason and verified by men in the course of a thousand years' experience: every idea or political action arises from an economic foundation which then plays both a controlling and determining role. In the course of this work we will examine, under different aspects, the inter-penetration of politics and economics and evaluate unions by taking a look at how they presently function.

Unions first appeared as defensive organs of the working class, faced with subhuman conditions of work, presenting themselves, on the industrial plane, as extensions of the old brotherhoods and corporations. On the basis of their aspirations unions do not even reach the level of reformism. Reformism, utilizing ideological and economic analyses, claims to demonstrate that, by means of capitalist democracy, it would be possible to attain socialism through a legal evolution and without any need for revolutionary acts. For unions there was never a question of either evolution or revolution, still less of socialism. Unions go no further than attempting to obtain, for the exploited worker, conditions of labor which are less intolerable and less humiliating, but also, as time has demonstrated, more profitable for capital. In spite of this limitation the early unions were organs which, if not revolutionary, at least had a working class spirit and a sound composition compared to the corruption and false class character of today's unions.

At the end of the 19th and the beginning of the 20th century a so-called revolutionary unionism (syndicalism) appeared. This was an eclectic doctrine adapted to the situation then prevailing, drawn from the Marxist conception, the so-called a-politicism of anarchism, and the strictly economic claims made by the old trade unions. There is no paradox in the fact that the period of the greatest influence and the strongest thrust of this type of unionism coincided with the apogee of reformism.

Sorel and Bernstein, besides being contemporaries, had more points in common than differences. While Sorel offered, in syndicalism, the panacea to the problems of historical development, Bernstein and his tendency saw in parliamentarism, and even in the necessities of capital accumulation, the happy mechanism of a certain and harmonious evolution towards socialist society. In reality revolutionary syndicalism and reformism were united by the same bonds to the formidable economic drive of the bourgeoisie. This was the period in which the bourgeoisie attained the zenith of its civilizing possibilities, granting the greatest amount of liberty and illusions to those who, without completely escaping its ideo-economic complex, leaned to the left. For this reason the political bankruptcy of 1914 would carry with it the syndicalists and reformists. Even the Spanish C.N.T. was not an exception, although the military neutrality of Spain spared it the capitulatory phrases and attitudes of the French C.G.T.; its particular bankruptcy, as we will see later, took place at the moment of the proletarian revolution in 1936-1939.

The numerical strength and the social weight of the unions has' grown continually since 1914 and if in some countries, like France, their numerical strength has considerable diminished in the course of the last few years their importance has continued to grow. It has been said that the disaster of 1914 was necessary for the unions to really come into their own. This is because until that time capitalism feared the unions as a destructive force and had not yet seen - except perhaps in England - the collaborative role that unions could play.But since the end of the first world war numerous experiences of ''worker's control'' in the factories have surprised the capitalists by their satisfactory effects. ''Worker's control'' has attenuated the struggle of workers against capital, facilitating the operation of the factories and above all increasing output. The unions stood out not only as defenders of the fatherland - that specifically capitalist entity - but as effective collaborators in the mmechanism of exploitation itself. That made their fortune and opened as yet unsuspected horizons to them. However, it was during the years 1936-1937-years which for many reasons were a very important landmark in the history of the international workers' movement that the unions took on their definitive orientation. In this period they displayed the qualities thanks to which they have become one of the most solid pillars of capitalist society.

Twenty years separated the Russian and the Spanish revolutions, which were the first and the last explosions of the same offensive of the world proletariat against capitalism, an offensive marked by incessant attacks in many other countries. Meanwhile the Stalinist bureaucracy had completed the construction of state capitalism and just at the moment when the Spanish revolution was in full swing the Stalinists got rid of all those who were really communists with guns and slander. This was to modify in a decisive manner all the organic factors of the class struggle and corrupt all the ideological factors. For a long time Russian intervention in the international workers' movement had been negative; in Spain the Russian-controlled Communist Party, dragged along by the requirements of its own preservation, turned out to be the principal counterrevolutionary police force. In July 1936 it attempted-happily in vain to prevent the uprising of the proletariat which destroyed the army throughout most of the country. In May 1937 this same Communist Party would machine gun the proletariat, which was revolting against the C.P.'s reactionary policies, defeat it, disarm it and crush the revolution. What the military had failed to do in 1936, Stalinism accomplished 10 months later.

For the first time Moscow acted, outside its own territory, directly as a counter-revolutionary force. Up to now there has been no real appreciation of the immense reactionary consequences of this event. Yet this was the source of all the acts of world importance which followed: from the Hitler-Stalin pact and the second "great war" till the policy of "peaceful coexistence" and uprisings such as those in Fast Germany, Poland and Hungary. The latter must be situated, not on the level of the revolt of the Spanish proletariat of May 1937, but at the most on the same level as the July 1936 insurrection, this time with the Stalinist army and police in place of Franco's army. Imre Nagy and his friends were in Hungary what the popular front was in Spain in 1936: the by-product of a revolutionary upheaval but not the core of the revolution.

It is significant that it was around 1936 that the unions revealed all their latent characteristics, incontestably manifesting themselves as auxiliary organs of capital. That in such a development it was Stalinism which won for itself the greatest influence in the unions - with the exception of the English and American trade unions - is quite natural. The economic empiricism of capitalism found in Russian counter-revolutionary empiricism a higher political expression, one which inspired it and perfected it at the same time. Both of these elements were mixed and merged to create a more favorable milieu. Now this milieu exists under a more or less completed form: it is nothing other than capitalism at its present stage, taking each country, including the "backward" ones, not as an isolated case but as part of the world system.

We will look at the Western bloc which prides itself on its democracy and more concretely on its right to strike. In reality this right is given not to the workers but to the representatives which the law recognizes them as having: the unions. Every strike launched by the workers themselves has to face a coalition of state and unions which seeks to smash it-sometimes by the direct defeat of the workers, sometimes by making the workers accept arbitration. Since the French revolutionary strike of 1936 was smashed by the Communist party (Thorez: "One must know how to end a strike") and the Socialist party together (the Blum government and police commanded by "socialists") almost every country has known strikes led to defeat by the unions because they ran counter to their economic and political interests. Thus, the strike has been in fact and in law taken over by the unions. But that is not all. Beyond the always exceptional situation of a strike, in the day-to-day relations between capital and labor-which is where the class struggle is forged-the unions appear not only as buffers between the two camps, but as messengers from capital to labor and as agents who help to adapt labor to the requirements of capital. All the natural manifestations of the struggle of labor against capital, once monopolized by the unions, are turned against the worker for the benefit of capital.

We have only to recall certain facts to see that the above line of reasoning is undeniable. Factory committees1 as well as delegates from departments, shops or occupational categories are not the expression of the free will of the workers, whatever may be the mode of their election, depending on the country. They represent the unions, within which workers are not free to elect anyone they want: even the famous British shop stewards need the assent of the trade unions. In most countries the law has decided that the unions which it recognizes represent the working class. The workers therefore no longer have the right to represent themselves as they see fit, still less to create organs other than unions in order to direct their struggles and to deal with the employers or the state. The rights of the working class and the rights of the unions are manifestly two distinct and contradictory things. Because of this the opposition between the workers and the factory committees or departmental delegates-an opposition which is always present in a latent form-sharpens whenever there is a conflict with the employer and becomes a direct encounter if the struggle broadens. In the course of the last twenty years every strike which deserves the name has had to be called against the will of the unions and by outflanking its representatives in the factories; the workers themselves have had to elect strike committees. However, every time that these strike committees or factory assemblies, elected by the workers, have allowed themselves to be influenced by the union leaders, capital has gained the upper hand.

The goal of collective labor contracts was to limit the arbitrariness of the employers in various areas: working conditions and the length of the working day, intensivity of exploitation (hourly productivity), wage range by category (hierarchical relations), hiring and layoffs, political rights, freedom of speech and assembly within the factories, factory regulations, etc. However, collective contracts have become, in the hands of the unions, who alone under the law have the right to negotiate and sign them, a formidable instrument for the subjugation of the proletariat to capital in general and to the unions in particular. Indeed, unions have become, at present, partially or totally, agents of exploitation. Layoffs and hiring are most often entrusted to the mercy of capital, except in the case of closed shops, which far from guaranteeing work for the laborers, simply grants the right of adjudication to the unions. This is reactionary economic coercion of the worst sort, as we will see below when we discuss unions in the Eastern zone.

Labor contracts sanction and encourage the division of the working class into hierarchical groups opposed to one another because of differences in wages and the prejudices attached to the category and technical function of the worker. The unions instinctively, by their very nature, contribute to the division of the proletariat on a hierarchical basis, except for which the proletariat would form a compact bloc against capital. The necessity of dividing the proletariat through hierarchical work relations, and of thus alienating it from its highest interest, is as important for the unions as it is for capital. For a century the workers' movement fought against hierarchical relations within its midst, and in large part it destroyed prejudices in favor of hierarchy while limiting its material bases. In the course of the last few decades the unions and their political inspirers have succeeded in largely re-establishing hierarchical prejudices and greatly increasing the number of work categories. Most workers today, even the worst off, think that hierarchical work relations are natural and ''just.''

Lastly, if the original idea of collective contracts was to put a curb on the arbitrariness of capital while awaiting its complete suppression, today they constitute an almost perfect way to regulate the capitalist system in accordance with its functional requirements. In negotiating and signing collective contracts the unions behave as if they were an integral part of the groups who monopolize the means of production. In the United States and in other countries, many unions are important shareholders in the companies which exploit their own members; which, far from prefiguring a socialist society, transforms the union into a beneficiary of exploitation in the fullest economic and ideological sense of the term. Where the unions do not actually participate in drawing up plans for the exploitation of the workers they seek this right.

The work place, the large factories in particular, which are the scene of the class struggle, afford the most revolutionary workers a permanent and far-reaching practical and ideological activity. But this activity is made impossible by the unions. Frequently collective contracts stipulate that political propaganda and activity within the factory are prohibited, not to speak of discussions and meetings which are indispensable to any working class activity. For many years the unions have conspired with the employers every time there was a question of dismissing revolutionary workers. Such dismissals are now legitimized by a written clause in collective contracts or surreptitiously acknowledged, since they are covered by the rules made by the employers in all the factories. The unions and their political inspirers have undertaken the task of acting as policemen against those who distribute revolutionary literature, when necessary beating them up. In Italy, the Stalinist union leaders have granted to the employers the right to fire, without notice or compensation, workers guilty of distributing literature or any type of agitation.2 In France, most of the factory rules permit as much and the restrictions on thought go so far that even the most rebellious workers are afraid to express themselves and so keep quiet. The situation is no better in Germany, England or the U.S., no more than in Russia or Spain. Thus, thanks to the convergent action of capital and the union organisations, the working class finds itself reduced to clandestinity even at the work place, which is where it is exploited and fucked over.

The proletariat must recover its political freedom, which is impossible without throwing the present employer-union legal framework overboard. The complete freedom of people with respect to the exercise of their labor contains, in embryo, the future revolutionary democracy and communism. We say communism because those who today call themselves communists are not communists at all and through legitimate revulsion towards them, those who really are communists often avoid claiming the name.

In the strictly economic domain the situation of the working class was never worse than it is today. Everything said to the contrary is so much bullshit. The eight-hour day, which should have been replaced long ago by a four or five hour day, now exists only on paper. In many countries the refusal to work overtime is an immediate cause for dismissal. Everywhere the introduction of so-called "basepay" (norm in Russia) which is deliberately kept low, and rewards and bonuses based on productivity, etc., not only forces the worker to accept, "of his own accord," working days of ten to twelve hours but in fact abolishes daily or hourly wages by imposing anew the vilest of all types of labor: piece-work. Since its inception the workers movement has endeavored to put an end to this oldest of all forms of exploitation, which physically exhausts the worker and dulls him intellectually.

It succeeded in eliminating piece-work in most of Europe. Even twenty years ago most workers considered it demeaning to accept piece-work of any kind. Today, however, piece-work is again the rule, less because capital has imposed it than through the deceit of the unions: in fact we have here a proof of the ultimate affinity of unions and capital.

With respect to the most profound aspect of exploitation,productivity per person and hour, the proletariat finds itself forced into a terrible situation. The production that is extracted from it each day increases at an enormous rate. First, technical innovations take away from the worker any creative intervention in his labor, measure his movements to the second and transform him into a living robot subjected to the same rhythm as the machines. Then, time studies, that atrocious and repugnant snare, force people to work over and over with the same tools and during uniform periods of time. Finally, the discipline of each enterprise reduces to a minimum the slightest suspicious of work even the lighting of a cigarette or taking a shit. The output that is extracted from each person by these means is enormous and so, in the same proportion, is the worker's physical and psychic exhaustion.

To mention this problem is to put one's finger on the evil of modern society and of the unions which are part of it. Moreover, there is no way to resolve these problems without overthrowing the present relation3 between production and distribution, in short, without making the revolution. But in order to treat this question properly it is necessary to first of all see what unions represent in Russia which is the model that the whole Eastern bloc, and even many countries beyond it, must imitate.

Everything that has been said about the reactionary work of unions and the deterioration of the proletarian condition in the West is even more true for the Russian world. Ever since, under Stalin's aegis, state capitalism was established in Russia, the whole of the old bourgeois world has been learning lessons in exploitation from it. These pertain to police repression too, but here we will limit ourselves to speaking about the specific relations between capital and labor and the role of the unions. Thus, if unions in general have, everywhere and for a long time, been a complementary force to capital within the working class, the Stalinist counter-revolution, by giving unions a very strong push in this direction and by providing them with a tempting example, has disclosed the intrinsic destiny of unions. Almost all the measures which, since 1936, have aggravated the exploitation of the proletariat in the West and heightened its objectification, have their model in Stalinist Russia.

The complete suppression of political rights and the right to hold meetings inside or outside the factory; overtime imposed by the employer or the inadequate base pay (norm) for the official working day; fines and disciplinary measures at the discretion of the employer, who also dictates the factory rules; time studies and innumerable controls, piecework, hierarchical divisions within the proletariat based on wages and technical "qualifications"; collective contracts which only benefit capital, continuous increase of productivity to the detriment of the producers, prohibition of strikes in fact or by law; in short, everything which in the West transforms the union organizations into more and more negative institutions received a strong impetus from the Russia of the 1930's and was to inspire capital and unions throughout the world.

It is well known, at least by those who are familiar with the situation in Russia, that economic inequality between the privileged and the exploited is greater there than anyplace else, as are the me qualities between different categories of workers. Inequality between the privileged and the exploited, which is at the same time the cause and the effect of capitalism, only concerns us in this essay as it affects the evolution and the prospects of the unions. It is sufficient to note for the moment that this inequality raises in Russia, as in every other country, the necessity for the expropriation of capital by the workers, which is impossible without an insurrection which completely demolishes the present governmental apparatus including the official party and the whole body of law.

Better than any bourgeoisie, the Stalinist bureaucracy knows how to intensify exploitation by accelerating the rhythm of labor and by introducing into the proletariat the greatest possible number of job categories. The traditional means for capitalism to "stimulate" production is to substitute for the homogeneous historical interest of the proletariat a multiplicity of heterogeneous immediate interests, which are so many obstacles to a common revolutionary activity. Once again the Russian union and political "natchalniks"4 have outdone their Western counterparts.5 In Russia the worker foremen receive a direct profit from the exploitation of their comrades in labor: the Stakhanovists receive a bonus which is proportional to the surpassing of the "norm" and to the number of workers in their team. Thus they see their wages increase by the exploitation of the common workers and are therefore led to intensify this exploitation. The Stakhanovists are therefore, still more clearly than foremen in the West (with their fixed salaries), turned into the enemies of their comrades in labor.

There is nothing astonishing in all this, since everything in Russia has been turned into its opposite. Once the revolution gave way to the counter-revolution, a capitalist dictatorship, which demagogically calls itself a proletarian dictatorship, presents - in reality imposes - as socialist the most rotten features and principles of traditional capitalism. The labor law, approved in 1939, says: The basic feature which characterizes wages in the capitalist countries is the levelling of wages between specialised and non-specialized workers. In the remuneration of labor, petit-bourgeois levelling is the worst enemy of socialism. For many years Marxism-Leninism has unceasingly fought against levelling.

For many years the Stalinists have tried to take people in by presenting industrial development through wage labor as the loyal expression of Marxist thought. Marxism, on the contrary, establishes as its objective the abolition of wage labor, and the economic levelling of society, the unlimited satisfaction of all individual needs and the greatest freedom and liberty, which is indispensable to any personal or collective fulfillment. If we do not aim at that, nothing revolutionary can be done in the present historical juncture. In the old capitalist countries wage differences within the proletariat are a condition established by the direct market relation between capital and labor. In Russia these wage differences have, by constitutional law, acquired the status of a principle and consequently it is a crime to fight against them. The traditional relation between capital and labor, which the bourgeoisie never justified as a social relation of man to man but only through the subterfuge of the sacred right of property" which in reality is turned against it when we consider as property, not the means of production or instruments of labor but everything which is necessary to the material consumption and the full psychic development of each person-is transformed in Russia into a natural and permanent relation between people having different abilities. Thus, instead of social classes or categories delimited in fact by wealth we have classes delimited by law on the basis of their talents and special functions. Nonetheless delimitation in fact on the basis of wealth takes on importance instead of losing it, Worse still the whole thing smacks of a biological justification for the exploitation of man by man.

Let us further point out that the principle object of the labor contracts imposed by the Russian unions is to put the working class at the mercy of capital, even juridically, "by guaranteeing the fulfilment and over-fulfillment of the state production plan for the given establishment."6 It is a question of extracting higher and higher rates of production from labor: The main stipulation of the contracted obligation must be an increased demand from every worker. Without strengthening labor discipline and without ruthless struggle against the violators of state and labor discipline -grabbers and loafers there can be no real fulfillment of obligations laid down in the collective agreement.7

The very word contract is a mark of servitude for the working class. Whether collective or individual, verbal or written, "free" or imposed, the labor contract is the legal symbol of its condition as a wage-slave class, to use Marx's term. This fact in itself is sufficient to expose the lies of the Russian exploiters. In a truly socialist economy neither capital nor wage labor would exist, and consequently the labor contract (the agreement for the utilization of the labor force) would disappear with the disappearance of the contracting parties. In a socialist economy, the means of production would cease to be capital and human labor power would cease to be a commodity for sale. United in one economic and social entity, they would be as free from any contractual obligations as an individual is toward himself. By its very existence, the Russian labor contract places itself within the framework of the social bonds characteristic of capitalism. But it is the ''innovations'' of the Russian system, particularly the completely overt way the unions assume the role of slave-drivers towards the workers, that reveal the ominous contours of a society in decline whose despots seem to be more capable than anyone else of checking proletarian resistance.

In effect, these contracts, whose main point is to extract the highest productivity possible from each worker, are drawn up by the unions and, after the formality of government approval, it is the unions duty to insure servility through promises of higher pay, by the use of threats or by turning over to legal prosecution those workers who do not go along with the demands of production. It is through union channels that the Russian government punishes, as if it were a crime, the struggle to work less and earn more (''The Right to be Lazy')8 which the world revolutionary movement has always considered to be a just claim of the working class and a progressive demand.

Thus in the eyes of the Russian workers the unions appear as the organization immediately responsible for their exploitation and for the cruelties characteristic of the counter-revolution. A great number of convincing documents (enough to fill several volumes) testify to this effect. It is impossible to list all of them here. One of the greatest weaknesses of the revolutionary movement, perhaps the cause of its limited support today, is the fact that it did not protest these ignominies. For the purposes of this article however it is enough to recall certain typically reactionary features of the Russian system: the laws forbidding workers to change jobs without the permission of the plant manager - laws which have long since been eliminated in older capitalist countries; laws establishing wages proportionate to the productivity of each individual worker (piece rates) not to mention bonuses for political servility; laws which punish absenteeism, lateness and other "disciplinary" infractions by fines, suspensions, firings and forced labor; laws which transform everything which revolutionary thought considers an outrage into something honourable and profitable; in short, all the laws which crush the proletariat as nowhere else are in Russia the direct work of the unions. This legislation is both proposed and carried out by the unions. Furthermore, the forced labor camps-' 're-education'' according to official jesuitry-the burial ground of workers and especially revolutionaries, the method deliberately chosen to lower wages and to be able to claim that unemployment is non-existent, are also "institutions" created on the initiative of the unions who share the advantages of this system with the state and with its essential instrument: the police.

One can argue that the Russian unions, as everyone knows, do not really act on their own initiative. But their repudiation by the workers is no less absolute. International experience indicates that unions in their structure and function vis-a'-vis the working class, always contained propitious elements for their transformation into a cog in the most centralized and absolute capitalist system.

Certainly the Russian unions blindly obey the orders of the government; they are only its vulgar instruments. But their own leaders are integrated into the highest levels of the Party and the state and thus become both "co-managers" ("co-owners") of an impersonal capital and at the same time "worker" leaders. Never could a company union dream of a more complete subjugation of the workers.

In Russia today the unions' function is part and parcel of the exploitative function of capital itself. The union is at the same time boss, foreman and policeman. In each factory it represents along with managers and technicians-all of whom are distinguished members of the union and of the "Communist " cell the same thing as Hitler's confidential councils (Vertrauenstrat). Furthermore, the complete intermixing of capital and Party-State has erased all trace of any union autonomy or protest activity. No one has to teach Russian workers this fact; they have cruelly suffered its consequences for many long years.

In the trajectory of Russian society, there is a definite break between the Soviet period and the period of the unions. Soviets were organizations which represented the workers, carried out their orders and those of the revolution. The unions on the other hand, are organizations of control over the workers executing the orders of the counter-revolution. The Soviets were paralyzed and finally disbanded while unions gained in importance and prerogatives as the bureaucracy increasingly revealed its counter-revolutionary nature. The proletariat was repressed to such an extent that today its subjection is nowhere as great as in Russia. Certainly it is not the unions alone which inspired the counter-revolution. They themselves are part of a whole series of bourgeois ideas and interests, vestiges from the tsarist period; its main basis was the high administrative bureaucracy, both technical and political, whose numbers and privileges have monstrously expanded. But in their turn the unions~mr if one prefers, their high-level leaders form an inseparable part of the whole category of state capitalists who rule the enormous corporation falsely called the "Soviet Union."

The interpenetration of the unions and the Russian counter-revolutionary bureaucracy was neither artificially imposed by the latter nor was it an accident. It is the spontaneous result of the intrinsic nature of unions from which the government assassinated or purged'' certain union leaders along with former revolutionaries.

The government eliminated them not for their union activities but for their communist attitude, either real or imagined. Because of their adaptive powers, the unions conformed perfectly to the specific aims and routine functioning of the counter-revolution. To understand this clearly, it suffices to examine the nature of unions.

Unions are totally inconceivable without the existence of wage-labor, which in turn presupposes the existence of capital. As long as capital is held by individual owners engaged in competition and represented by many individuals and parties in the government, unions are at least able to bargain for an improvement in the conditions of labor exploitation. Their function is to regularize the sale of labor power, a function which has become indispensable to the modern capitalist system. From this fact comes their importance as complementary structures of the state, if not part of the state itself, everywhere in the world today. But this very function, which in the past allowed unions to at least serve as instruments of the working class was also a narrowness indicating their limitations and reactionary future. Their existence as an organization is entirely dependent on the continued existence of the labor/capital duality. They would be immediately eliminated by the destruction of this duality. However, they can side with capital as much as they choose without destroying this duality. On the contrary, they become increasingly indispensable to the maintenance of the capitalist system. As a result, the more gigantic and anonymous the concentration of capital, the more the unions take the side of capital and consider their role to be directly determined by the great "national" interest. Even Stalinist union leaders in the West, agents of Russian imperialism, are careful to present their union policies as an element of national welfare. They are not lying; their only future is to establish themselves as the firmest bastion of statified capital.

All unions without exception are in the process of changing from the stage of ''free competition'' between the supply and demand of labor power between the working class and the bourgeois into the stage of the control of the supply by the demand: that is, the control of workers by monopolistic or state capital. In most cases the unions already participate, directly or indirectly, in the profits of capitalism or else they sense the opportunity to do so.9 In Russia this evolution was completed with the counter-revolutionary transformation of the country in general. The law bestows on the unions all power over the working class without leaving the smallest possibility for workers, collectively or individually to discuss, accept or reject the conditions of their exploitation. All working conditions-even what the workers should think -are directly dictated by the unions in the name of capital. As always, economics and politics intertwine and end up united in the most strict absolutism.

The historical examples of a truly working-class unionism were all the results of revolutionaries' activities and belong to an age (which ended with the Spanish Revolution) which allowed a certain margin for the class struggle within capitalism. But today revolutionaries who stubbornly persist in regarding unions as any sort of advantage for the future of socialism are condemning themselves to ineffectiveness or worse: betrayal. The past struggles of French, Spanish, or Italian syndicalism were the rest of the activity of revolutionary tendencies, either marxist or anarchist. The Spanish CNT would have been nothing without the FAI (Iberian Anarchist Federation) and it is the FAI itself which must be held responsible for the reactionary alliance with Stalinism during the Civil War. The year 1936 marks the bankruptcy of Spanish syndicalism comparable (in all ways) to the bankruptcy of the French CGT in 1914. Not only did the FAI-CNT voluntarily submit to Stalinism (a submission presented, as usual, in the interests of "national welfare") but it established an alliance with the leaders of the reformist UGT, an alliance which would have meant, in explicit enough terms, state capitalism. The CNT will never pick itself up after such a fall. Any revolutionary group coming from these roots must seek other horizons.

The collectivist experiences in Spain were only syndicalist by default. This movement was set off by the impetus of revolutionary militants and by highly radicalized sections of the masses; the unions found themselves faced with a fait accompli. The same can be said of the uprising against the military on July 19, 1936 and of the magnificent insurrection of May, 1937. When, after revolutionary action, the unions intervene and take over, the entire process is reversed: the activity of the proletariat and the participation of revolutionaries recedes and retreats-the prelude to defeat. In the same vein, the experiences of the strike in Nantes10 in 1956 should be remembered. The strike, the work of several revolutionary militants in the local union, was betrayed by the national union. Hundreds of similar examples can be found in any country in the world. Attempts to give unions a revolutionary content, through the use of internal oppositional caucuses or even by creating completely new unions, are doomed to failure. The only result of such "tactics" is to demoralize the revolutionary experience of those who attempt it or to turn them into simple bureaucrats. Unions bring to bear all the powerful, deformative forces of capitalist society which constantly eat away at men, changing and destroying even the best of them. There is about as much possibility of "changing" unions in a revolutionary direction as there is of "changing" capitalist society in general; unions use men for their own particular ends but men will never be able to make unions serve a revolutionary goal; they must destroy them.

Attempts to "change" unions are futile even from a practical point of view. In most countries workers are no longer in unions. Even if they still carry a union card in their pocket, whether voluntarily or because the law forces them to do so, the suspicion and disgust they feel for unions is no less strong. In countries which have had the most extensive experience with unions, workers have recourse to unions only if they feel that their "rights" under capitalist law are being flagrantly violated. This is a tedious formality but necessary, on the same level as going to the police when something is stolen. But everyone knows it is useless to go to unions to get something outside the limits of capitalist "law" because unions are a part of that law. Consequently, we see, in many cases, a decline in the number of union members and a general desertion from union meetings by the majority of workers. Unions, having a bureaucratic and legal life of their own, merely use the working class as a docile mass to manipulate in order to Increase their own power as a legal institution in our society. Unions and working people have completely different daily lives and motivations. Any ''tactical" work within unions, even if guided by the purest intentions, will impede the self-activity of the exploited class, destroying their fighting spirit and barring the way to revolutionary activity.

Lenin and Trotsky's position on revolutionary work within unions is entirely outside the realm of today's realities. Their position explicitly supposes that the proletariat, otherwise inexperienced and unorganized and full of illusions, meets in the unions where freedom of speech would permit revolutionaries to expose the opportunist leadership and thereby spread revolutionary ideas.11 In addition to the argument citing the prevalence of workers' illusions about unions, the key premise of the Leninist tactic was the fact that unions were considered as ideologically reformist and therefore supposedly interested in wresting concessions from the declining society by playing left-wing to the "liberal democrats" of an earlier age. These conditions no longer exist and those who continue to gear their activity towards them are acting in vain. Fifty times the proletariat has tried the experience of unions and of the parties which dominate them and they have changed in an undeniably reactionary direction. To act towards them as though they were still reformist is a ridiculous expression of today's opportunism.

The most solid basis for a revolutionary critique of unions concerns not tactical or contingent considerations but the question of principle and strategy. These questions had not been taken into account by Lenin and Trotsky probably because the changes in unions had not clearly developed until the last few decades. The fact is that unions and their political inspirers have been completely assimilated by the capitalist world, not as part of the "democratic wing" of the bourgeoisie but as henchmen for the exploitative society and for the new needs of the counter-revolution. The polemic between Lenin, Trotsky and Tomsky on the union question, which occurred before the sinister shadow of the Stalinist police had ravaged revolutionary thought, finds its synthesis after long periods of trial and error, in the political conclusions of this article.

There are still revolutionaries who refuse to see the problem and repeat like a credo: "since the conditions which gave rise to unions still exist, we do not see how today one can deny their utility." At the same time they postpone the elimination of unions until the moment when the ''specific characteristics of bourgeois society disappear,'' that is, when the separation between workers and instruments of production has disappeared.12 This is more sententious subterfuge than reasoned argument. In a sense this argument can be used against itself. If when we speak of conditions which have given rise to unions, we mean the purchase of human labor power by the monopolizers of the means of production, or in a more general way, the characteristic relations of capitalist society as a whole, then it is clear that unions are part of this whole network of relations and that unions continue to exist with it and for it. From this point of view, to attribute a useful function to unions in the revolutionary process is as unthinkable as seeing revolutionary potential in the stock market. Unions are as much a part of capitalist value production as the stock market, even if we examine only the aspects of the dealing and contracting of wage labor, aspects which are not unconnected to the values quoted on the stock market.

In addition to these conditions which gave rise to unions, conditions of a historically more limited nature must be dealt with. In the period of capitalist ascendancy, free competition, including free competition in the labor market, permitted workers to benefit from the greatest number of advantages compatible with the system. The regulation and administration of these advantages constituted the fundamental raison d 'etre of unions. However, with the system's transformation into giant trusts and state capitalism, the unions, which it nourished, naturally began to play a reactionary role. They could not continue to maintain their function without adapting themselves to changing market conditions now no longer free but controlled and despotic, indeed malthusian since it prevents the realization of human and economic potential.

Thus in a strict sense the conditions which gave rise to unions no longer exist; they died at the same time as that which justified the existence of capitalism as a historically progressive social form. Unfortunately it is the revolutionaries who are way behind in recognizing the facts and drawing the logical conclusions.

The reasoning of Programma Communista which offers the best theoretical justification for all tendencies (including anarchism) still clinging to an oppositional or revolutionary unionism, is in fact completely mistaken. Their reasoning is very dangerous especially in the event of a victorious revolution. The subterfuge of putting off the disappearance of unions until the obliteration of all traces of capitalism - until the advent of full communism - would give unions a harmful monopoly over the proletariat in the transitional period. Far from bringing society closer to communism, this would raise still another obstacle, and not a minor one, promoting the growth of state capitalism as it did in Russia. Bordiga 's analysis links the disappearance of unions to the disappearance of violence within the Society, meaning in fact the disappearance of the state. However, the withering away of the state and of all social violence can only be a consequence of a Preceeding disappearance of the exploitation of labor, wage labor to be exact. Unions are in complete contradiction to such a transformation, both in terms of interest and principle.

A century ago Karl Marx reproached unions for restricting their demands to questions of money, hours of work, etc., while they ignored the issue of the abolition of wage labor, the key to the destruction of capitalism. Today, Marx would be treated as a petty-bourgeois egalitarian by the men of Moscow and as a crazy ultra-leftist by those who believe they can reform unions. Marx did not see the elimination of unions as part of the far-distant future, well after the revolution, but as concomitant with the revolution or even its cause. He believed that already in his lifetime the industrialized countries disposed of sufficient material means to tackle the problem of revolution. We, revolutionaries of today, are able to add that unions stand in the way of every aim of social revolution because they have become an indispensable cog in the machinery of the exploitation of man by man. Their role in the present economy is comparable to that of the guilds in the age of small-scale manufacture - with this difference however: guilds proved unable to adapt to large-scale industry whereas unions adapt perfectly to the most resolute type of capitalism, the statified form. Unions will be destroyed only by the victory of the revolution; more precisely their destruction is a pre-condition for this victory, without which the unions will continue to grow into a huge coercive apparatus complementary to the state capitalist machine. That is the greatest counter-revolutionary danger of our time. If humanity proves unable to face this problem in the West as well as in the Stalinist East, it will witness the most ominous era of our history.

After the revolution, all workers (without need of any union affiliation whatsoever) must decide on the economic questions posed by society's progress towards communism. No organization, whether a union or a party can be identified wit the society as a whole or invested with its attributes. The existence of differing ideological currents (based on the foundations of the revolution) all competing for a majority will only further insure the possibility of direct participation of all in social decisions. But a union-style management of the economy will necessarily prove anti-democratic and stifling; it would exclude non-members and impose itself on everyone. Of course ideologies can degenerate or betray but only through the spread and growth of revolutionary ideas can man win his freedom. Even today the proletariat's immediate demands elude union formulations. Faced with exploitation heightened by technology, forced overtime, piecework, speed-up, etc., it is essential to demand a reduction of the work day to a maximum of five to six hours without reduction of wages or bonuses. On such a basis, demands for constantly decreasing work schedules in inverse proportion to technological progress are urgently neeeded. This is the way to challenge today's crushing work day and to prefigure a reorganisation of socially necessary work by eliminating the enormous amounts of waste production in industry as well as in the government and administrative bureaucracies.

The necessary complement to this demand is the refusal to go along with any increase in production, whether caused by improvements in machinery or by speed-up, unless the working class benefits; the working class represents the interests of society as a whole. This is an unlimited demand, not only against capitalism and its threats of constant war, but as an idea of the kind of considerations which would govern a future revolutionary society; underlying this demand is the necessity for the destruction of the present system.

Politically, workers must impose complete freedom at the point of production the rejection of all rules which have not been decided upon by workers' delegates democratically elected and approved in general assembly. In the case of problems or conflicts, workers' committees, elected outside of all union structures, are revocable at any time. Any agreement with management must have the consent of the interested parties themselves and not the unions even if they claim to represent the majority. Finally, co-ordination among the different workers' committees would prepare the way for the demand, as an immediately realizable objective, for workers' control of production and distribution.

A careful study of the problems which face the working class today would only reinforce these conclusions. The three types of problems, which encompass all the others, amply demonstrate the reactionary conservatism of unions and the fact that it is impossible for the workers to make a move ahead without coming up against them. Without getting rid of them, the proletariat will never get out of its present difficulties and will never have a revolutionary perspective.

The future of unions is indisputably linked with that of capitalism and not the revolution. Their ability to adjust to the reac-tionary transformation of society was largely overlooked by even the most far-seeing revolutionaries. An exception must be made for an almost unknown theoretician, Daniel DeLeon, whose thoughts on this subject have proven visionary. From 1905 DeLeon saw that unions and the "official" workers' parties harbored serious counter-revolutionary dangers. The work in which he succinctly expressed his ideas deserves the attention of all revolutionaries.13

DeLeon's judgments are excellent historical analyses which he expresses with revolutionary passion. On the basis of international experience, particularly with the British and American trade unions and their respective labor leaders, he predicts that the victory of these organizations would kill any social revolution.

The present labor leaders represent a disguised position, a strategic point and a force sustaining capitalism and their true nature cannot but produce a disastrous de-moralization of the working class.

He compares the labor leaders and their organizations with the leaders of the plebs in Rome. Just as the pleb leaders used the plebeians to acquire the rights and privileges of the patrician class without giving anything more than crumbs to the dispossessed masses, modern labor leaders and their organizations use the proletariat to consolidate their economic and political position within the capitalist system of exploitation.

Like the leaders of the plebs,labor leaders are practical men as they boast; they do not live on visions or chase rainbows. Like the pleb leaders, labor leaders do not see any alternative to the existing social system, and they aim to put out the flame that devours the working class. Like the plebeian leaders of Rome, today's labor leaders, if we do not counteract them . ..they will nullify all the possibilities which our age offers: they will divert the important and powerful actions of the masses until they lose the name of action.

The aptness of the comparison between the leaders of the Roman plebs and our union (and party) bureaucrats is even clearer if we examine the role of the so-called plebeian party in Roman history. This party, born in the time of the Tarquins, supposedly in irreconcilable opposition to the patrician ruling classes, enjoyed its greatest influence during the Republican period. Its power did not serve the true plebs, the poor masses, either slave' or free, but worked to the benefit of a privileged minority which represented the plebs in name only and belonged to the plebeian class only by the accident of Roman legal definition. Caesar and Augustus, the founders of Empire, constantly used the trick of referring to themselves as originally "plebs" or "on the pleb side." Their victory, the high point of the party of the pleb leaders, destroyed forever all possibility of revolution in Rome. The plebeian usurpers replaced by and large the old patrician class. They did not open the way to a new or superior type of Society but merely prolonged the decadence of the ancient world over which they presided in its final stage.

Despite the great structural and ideological differences between Greco-Roman civilization and capitalist civilization, the analogy between the role of the pleb leaders and today's labor leaders is close Whether they call themselves apolitical, Communist or Socialist they have substituted for the principle contradiction of capitalism that which can only disappear with its destruction-another unessential contradiction inscribed within the functional necessities of capitalism and for which the ''Solution'' makes them indispensable to the exclusion of any revolutionary intervention of the worker’s.

The bourgeoisie and the proletariat are the human profile, the anthropomorphic image of the social contradictions between capital and wage labor. This contradiction is unresolvable except with the abolition of capital-an act which must Simultaneously abolish wage labor itself. Here ends capitalism and begins the social revolution: a new, unlimited horizon of a new civilization.

The Spirit of the so-called labor leaders as well as their organizations are absolutely incompatible with the solution of this contradiction. They attempt to resolve only a secondary contradiction within the framework of exploitation- that is, the anarchy of private capitalism with its cyclical crises which calls for an ordered plan of production and a severe regimentation of manpower, the unemployed included. In this way, the interests of the labor leaders coincide with that of big capital which every day demands more economic regulation, more concentration. In other words, that which they perceive and want to change are the difficulties which the System encounters on the road to one huge monopoly, not at all the difficulties which the system as a whole poses for the forward march of humanity towards communism. With the concentration of all the means of production in a huge state monopoly, labor-upon which depends consumption, liberty, culture, the whole life of human beings-appears as an element which is as subordinate to the exigencies of the plan as iron ore, leather or any other raw material. The elimination of the bourgeoisie does not in any way mean the elimination of capital or the proletariat. Capital is an economic function, not a proprietary function; in becoming an anonymous function it completes its oppression of man and bars his march to communism with new counter-revolutionary force. The use of the purely anthropomorphic representation of the contradiction between capital and wage labor (bourgeoisie and proletariat) gives the union and party leaders the opportunity to present the elimination of private capital as the elimination of capital in general and their economic and political management as the solution of social contradictions. They know from the experiences of the Stalinist counter-revolution and from Yankee and British trade unions that the more complete the concentration of capital, the bigger the share of profits for them to pocket.

The most menacing aspect of this tendency of the labor leaders is that it coincides with the law of capitalist concentration and with the development of material and ideological coercion which is its consequence. But they are really dangerous only because of the passivity of the proletariat, whom the revolutionaries, attached to the old ideas and tactics, do not know how to stir into action. Chained to the old formulae, they are cursed with sterility. But a careful look around suffices to realize that the human necessity of a total transformation challenges capitalism itself and the labor leaders, a challenge which will open an unlimited field to revolutionary action.

Humanity does not need technocratic plans in order to produce plans which are used for exploitation and war. The crisis which our civilization is living through will not find its solution until all of production is oriented towards consumption without regard to selling. All individuals by their very existence must be able to utilize the material and spiritual resources of the society. The marketing of one or the other leads to the dissatisfaction of the immense majority, the impossibility of individual fulfiflmnt and the venality of culture. Only the elimination of individual proprietors and the giant trusts will lead to the elimination of the proletariat: the class which does not consume but lives only on its salary. Thus it is wage labor which must be eliminated. In this way capital will necessarily be abolished as an economic function along with the exploiters, be they bourgeois or bureaucrats. Any plan for production must be established with regard to the non-mercantile needs of human consumption, with all that these words imply of political and cultural liberty. The true anthropomorphic aspect of the problem is the abolition of wage labor which will give to man the possibility of determining his own destiny. By substituting for this the idea of simply eliminating the bourgeoisie (and by putting themselves in its place) union leaders offer us a series of fetishes-the economic plan in place of God, father and judge of man with the big union and party bureaucrats playing the role of the priesthood.

Revolutionaries must expel from the factories and professional organizations all the union representatives; and all the Thorez', the Nennis and the Reuthers of all countries, with the Vatican crouching behind the Christian unions, will be paralyzed. The working class will have regained its freedom of thought and action and will be able to transform society from top to bottom. It will have gained the strength to wrest humanity from the mire of degradation.

  • 1. Here Munis is referring to organs which are part and parcel of the union apparatus and not autonomous factory committees.
  • 2. A worker reading l'Unita, the Stalinist newspaper, inside the factory is dismissed with out a hearing, with the agreement of the Stalinist leaders who have co-signed this clause.
  • 3. between instruments of labor and wage labor
  • 4. A pejorative term applied by the people to the present rulers
  • 5. During the honeymoon of Russo-American relations, towards the end of World War II, the heads of the Yankee monopolies (including among others, Johnston, then President of the Chamber of Commerce) having been invited by Moscow to visit its industrial enterprises, lavishly praised the methods of "Soviet" exploitation that the American workers, or so they complained, prevented them from applying.
  • 6. Trud, the official Russian trade union paper, Feb.19, 1947, cited by Solomon M. Schwarz, Labor in the Soviet Union, London 1952, p.280.
  • 7. Ibid. The 1917 revolution called for the disappearance of wage labor and capital. That is why a reformist critic, Zagorsky,, defined the economy of the revolutionary epoch as "an enormous charity program. Beginning with the N.E.P. (New Economic Policy), there clearly began a movement in the opposite direction, which acquired the character of state capitalism with the Stalinist counter-revolution. Up to that point contracts were individual even if they were not written down. The systemization of collective contracts runs parallel to the establishment of a state capitalism which seeks stability and permanence.
  • 8. "Le droit I' la paresse," Paul Lafargue, 1898.
  • 9. possible exceptions to this trend do not fundamentally weaken the above argument. It should be noted that the "exceptions" are not to be found in underdeveloped countries but more likely in the older countries of Europe. In underdeveloped countries, where unions are or seem to be new developments, they voluntarily accept being in the service of the bourgeoisie or the state. Often different unions in the same trade engage in cut-throat competition to offer their manpower to the bosses at the cheapest rate.
  • 10. One of the most significant strikes in France during the 50's.
  • 11. Lenin, Left-wing Communism 1920.
  • 12. The Italian political tendency of Bordiga whose arguments we combat here (IL Programma Communista, May 26, 1960) defends the conservative union tactic from the most revolutionary point of view. But many Trotskyist and anarchist groups (if not all) fall into the same error with an opportunist flavor. Even those who claim to be against the unions, like "Socialisme ou Barbarie," in fact fall into the same old routine practices.
  • 13. Two Pages From Roman History. 1. PIeb Leaders and Labor Leaders, II. the Warning of the Gracchi (New York 1946).

 

 

 

 

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

They Don’t Get It

  • 분류
    계급투쟁
  • 등록일
    2011/10/14 08:54
  • 수정일
    2011/10/14 08:54
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

They Don’t Get It (Revised)

The following is a revised version of our leaflet posted on October 6, 2011. In addition to US events, it will be distributed in Canada and Belgium this weekend.

 

THEY DON’T GET IT….

 

When the media talk about Occupy Wall Street, they often do so with disdain: a movement that has no leaders, no set of demands, can’t be taken seriously. In a typical article, the New York Times quoted an ‘expert’ saying, “if the movement is to have lasting impact, it will have to develop leaders and clear demands”, and another one which stated that the passions have to be “channeled into institutions”. (NYT, 10/4) Their message to you is clear: ‘Go back to ‘politics as usual’, follow leaders, work within institutions, become foot-soldiers for the Democratic party and the unions in elections and other campaigns that change nothing at all, that don’t question the power structures that prop up this insane money-system.

 

They don’t get it that the absence of leaders in this movement is not a weakness but a strength, testifying to our collective determination, to our refusal to remain followers. They don’t get it that the absence of a narrow set of demands that can be recuperated by this or that institution, results from our understanding that the problem lies much deeper. That there are no quick fixes for a system that produces growing inequality, mass unemployment and misery, wars and ecological disasters.

 

If these problems could be solved by electing wiser politicians, adopting better laws etc, ‘politics as usual’ might be the way to go. But they can’t be solved that way. Politicians everywhere are bound by higher laws, the laws of capital. That’s why governments everywhere, regardless of their political color, are imposing austerity, forcing the working population to sacrifice so that more can be paid to the owners of capital. In fact the harshest cuts in wages, pensions and jobs are implemented by a ‘socialist’ government (in Greece). Politicians on the left may clamor for massive public spending , but that would only mean that we would be made poorer in a different way, through inflation.

 

There are no quick fixes because the system itself is obsolete. Pain and suffering are sometimes unavoidable but capitalism creates ever more pain that is easily avoidable, that only exists because in this society, profit trumps human needs. Almost two billion people on this planet are unemployed because capitalism has no need for them. Hundreds of millions live in slums, because building decent houses for them is not profitable. Many die of hunger each day because it’s not profitable to feed them. Everyone knows our planet is in danger and yet capitalism is continuing to destroy it in its desperate hunt for profit. Productivity never was higher, yet poverty increases. The know-how and resources are there for every inhabitant of this planet to live a decent life but that would not be profitable. Abundance has become possible but capitalism can’t handle abundance. It needs scarcity. Abundance in capitalism means overproduction, crisis, misery. This is insane. It must stop.

 

 

WE HAVE TO THINK OUTSIDE THE BOX

 

Capitalism is not “the end of history” but just a transient phase. It has changed the world but now no longer fits into it. We have to accept the fact that capitalism offers no perspective, no future. We have to prepare for a post-capitalist world, in which human relations are no longer commercial transactions, in which goods no longer represent a quantity of money but a concrete means to satisfy real human needs. A world in which competing corporations and warring nations are replaced by a human community that uses the resources of all for the benefit of all. We call that communism but it has nothing in common with the state-capitalist regimes that exist or existed in Russia, China and Cuba. Nothing is changed fundamentally if capitalists are replaced with bureaucrats with supposedly better intentions. Those regimes were not only thoroughly undemocratic, they also perpetuate wage-labor, exploitation and oppression of the vast majority of the population. The change must go deeper and must emancipate the oppressed, make them part of a real democracy instead of the sham that exists today.

 

In 2011, ten years after the attacks on New York that launched a decade of fear and demoralization, a breach has been opened. From Tunis to Cairo to Athens to Madrid to Santiago to New York, a fever is spreading. After taking it on the chin for so long, the working class, employed or unemployed, is beginning to rise up. We’re not gonna take it anymore! Something has changed. True, the Occupy Wall Street movement will not last forever. At some point, it will end, without any clear victory. But it’s just the beginning. This dynamic will continue and will gather strength. Be a part of it!

 

 

THERE’S MORE…

 

It’s clear that the”Occupy Wall Street”-movement has touched a nerve. Its message resonates throughout the country, even throughout the world. Everywhere people are raising their voice in protest against a system that produces increasing misery for the many and absurd wealth for the few. No wonder that the unions, progressive Democrats, even the President, and governors like Cuomo who is imposing draconian austerity on workers in NY, are attaching their wagons to this train, in order to get control over the locomotive. Don’t be fooled: These political tendencies are themselves the representatives of the 1%, of the banks and the capitalist system, not of the 99%. Let’s not allow our movement to be co-opted by the very powers in opposition to which it has arisen. The left of capital cynically claims that they want ‘economic justice’, too; that they seek a more just distribution of the wealth, through taxation of the rich, etc. (that’s their rhetoric, their practice is something else, see Cuomo’s recent move to kill the ‘billionnaires tax’ because it would chase the rich away).

 

The truth is that the unfairness, the unjust distribution of wealth, is built into the system and can’t be taken out of it. It will only increase more as capitalism sinks deeper into its crisis, for which it knows no way out (to throw more money in the economy or to save: they’re damned if they do and damned if they don’t). ‘Redistribution of wealth’ is an incomplete demand that can get nowhere if it’s not pushed further. As a slogan of May ’68 claimed: ‘Be realistic, demand the impossible”. The impossible within capitalism, that is. Although there are quite a few capitalists who profit from the crisis, overall, capitalism suffers from it too, so that there is less wealth to redistribute (and the competition between nations for capital assures that the 1% suffers least and the 99% most). No utopian plan for redistribution can address this shrinkage of wealth.

 

But what is wealth? In this society, goods and services equal money, abstract value that can be endlessly amassed, possessed ad infinitum, or, when no buyer is found, they equal pure waste. So money, abstract value, decides what is produced and what not. That is the box we’ve got to get out of. We have to abandon the idea that wealth is money, that work is wage-labor and start to see production of goods and services as things we can create for each other. We must realize that when we come together we can use the creative powers that humankind has to make technology, housing, food, transportation, art and so much more for everybody because the need is there, instead of for profit. Let’s get rid not just of Wall Street, but the whole exploitation-for-money-system. This perspective may seem utopian to many today, but it will become increasingly realistic as the crisis of capitalism deepens.

 

INTERNATIONALIST PERSPECTIVE

 

They Don’t Get It

The following leaflet was handed out at the Occupy Wall Street demo today in Manhattan:

 

THEY DON’T GET IT….

 

When the media talk about Occupy Wall Street, they often do so with disdain: a movement that has no leaders, no set of demands, can’t be taken seriously. In a typical article, the New York Times quoted an ‘expert’ saying, “if the movement is to have lasting impact, it will have to develop leaders and clear demands”, and another one which stated that the passions have to be “channeled into institutions”. (NYT, 10/4) Their message to you is clear: ‘Go back to ‘politics as usual’, follow leaders, work within institutions, become foot-soldiers for the Democratic party and the unions in elections and other campaigns that change nothing at all, that don’t question the power structures that prop up this insane money-system.

 

They don’t get it that the absence of leaders in this movement is not a weakness but a strength, testifying to our collective determination, to our refusal to remain followers. They don’t get it that the absence of a narrow set of demands that can be recuperated by this or that institution, results from our understanding that the problem lies much deeper. That there are no quick fixes for a system that produces growing inequality, mass unemployment and misery, wars and ecological disasters.

 

If these problems could be solved by electing wiser politicians, adopting better laws etc, ‘politics as usual’ might be the way to go. But they can’t be solved that way. Politicians everywhere are bound by higher laws, the laws of capital. That’s why governments everywhere, regardless of their political color, are imposing austerity, forcing the working population to sacrifice so that more can be paid to the owners of capital. In fact the harshest cuts in wages, pensions and jobs are implemented by a ‘socialist’ government (in Greece). Politicians on the left may clamor for massive public spending , but that would only mean that we would be made poorer in a different way, through inflation.

 

There are no quick fixes because the system itself is obsolete. Pain and suffering are sometimes unavoidable but capitalism creates ever more pain that is easily avoidable, that only exists because in this society, profit trumps human needs. Almost two billion people on this planet are unemployed because capitalism has no need for them. Hundreds of millions live in slums, because building decent houses for them is not profitable. Many die of hunger each day because it’s not profitable to feed them. Everyone knows our planet is in danger and yet capitalism is continuing to destroy it in its desperate hunt for profit. Productivity never was higher, yet poverty increases. The know-how and resources are there for every inhabitant of this planet to live a decent life but that would not be profitable. Abundance has become possible but capitalism can’t handle abundance. It needs scarcity. Abundance in capitalism means overproduction, crisis, misery. This is insane. It must stop.

 

 

WE HAVE TO THINK OUTSIDE THE BOX

 

Capitalism is not “the end of history” but just a transient phase. It has changed the world but now no longer fits into it. We have to accept the fact that capitalism offers no perspective, no future. We have to prepare for a post-capitalist world, in which human relations are no longer commercial transactions, in which goods no longer represent a quantity of money but a concrete means to satisfy real human needs. A world in which competing corporations and warring nations are replaced by a human community that uses the resources of all for the benefit of all. We call that communism but it has nothing in common with the state-capitalist regimes that exist or existed in Russia, China and Cuba. Nothing is changed fundamentally if capitalists are replaced with bureaucrats with supposedly better intentions. Those regimes were not only thoroughly undemocratic, they also perpetuate wage-labor, exploitation and oppression of the vast majority of the population. The change must go deeper and must emancipate the oppressed, make them part of a real democracy instead of the sham that exists today.

 

In 2011, ten years after the attacks on New York that launched a decade of fear and demoralization, a breach has been opened. From Tunis to Cairo to Athens to Madrid to Santiago to New York, a fever is spreading. After taking it on the chin for so long, the working class, employed or unemployed, is beginning to rise up. We’re not gonna take it anymore! Something has changed. True, the Occupy Wall Street movement will not last forever. At some point, it will end, without any clear victory. But it’s just the beginning. This dynamic will continue and will gather strength. Be a part of it!

 

INTERNATIONALIST PERSPECTIVE

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

<세계혁명> 경제불황, 전쟁, 사회해체- 계급투쟁만이 해결책이다

  • 분류
    계급투쟁
  • 등록일
    2011/10/06 08:36
  • 수정일
    2011/10/06 15:40
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

경제불황, 전쟁, 사회해체- 계급투쟁만이 해결책이다

 

 

 Not dead yet

올 여름 경제위기의 극적인 첨예화는 자본주의 체제가 그 한계에 다달았음을 분명하게 보여준다. '부채위기'는 문자그대로 은행의 파산일뿐만 아니라 전체 국가들의 파산을 백일하에 드러냈고, 게다가 그리스나 포르투갈과 같이 경제가 허약한 나라들 뿐만 아니라 유로지역의 주요국가들, 특히 세계경제최강대국 미국도 포함된다.

 

그리고 이 위기는 전세계적일 뿐만 아니라 역사적이기도 하다. 지난 몇년간 뚜렷하게 모습을 드러낸 빚더미는 1960년대말 1970년대초에 이미 나타난 경제위기를 자본주의가 늦추거나 은폐하려한 시도들의 결과일 뿐이다. 또한 오늘의 '침체'가 진정한 불황으로서의 본 모습을 드러내면서, 우리는 이것이 실상, 1930년대에 생산을 마비시켰고 그당시 세계를 제국주의전쟁으로, 즉 제 2차세계대전으로 몰아갔던 위기과 같은 심각한 위기임을 인식해야 한다. 이 위기는 자본주의 체제가 역사적으로 쇠퇴했음을 보여준다.

 

오늘의 불황과 1930년대의 불황사이의 차이는 오늘의 자본주의는 어떤 수단도 갖고 있지 않다는데 있다. 1930년대에 지배계급은 그 위기에 대항한 그들 자체의 야만적인 해법, 즉 제국주의 전쟁에 전 사회를 동원하고 세계를 새롭게 분활하는 것을 관철시킬 수 있었다. 재조직화는 2차 세계대전 후, 1950년대와 1960년대에 있었던 재건의 기적의 토대를 만들어냈다. 그 당시 이러한 가능성이 존재했던 것은 부분적으로, 세계대전이 자동적으로 자본주의의 자기파괴를 의미하지 않았기 때문이며, 또 전후에 새로운 제국주의 종주국의 출현 여지가 여전히 존재했기 때문이다. 그러나 그것은 또한 그리고 무엇보다도 하나의 옵션이었는데, 이는 그 이전에 노동자계급이 1차 세계대전에 뒤이어 혁명을 시도했었고 그러면서 스탈린주의, 파시즘 그리고 민주주의로 인해 그 역사상 가장 심각한 배패를 경험했었기 때문이다.

 

오늘날 세계대전은 추상적이고 이론적인 의미에서만 하나의 옵션이다. 사실상 전세계적인 제국주의전쟁으로의 길은 자본주의가 옛 양대 블록 구도의 붕괴 후 그 어떤 안정적인 제국주의적 연합도 이뤄낼 수 없다는 점 때문에 막혀있다. 그 길은 또한 자본주의 주요국가들에서 착취당하는 사람들 대다수를 이 체제는 그 수호를 위해 투쟁하고 죽을 만한 가치가 있는 것이라고 설득하고 단합시킬 수 있는 이데올로기가 존재하기 않는다는 점에 의해서도 마찬가지로 가로막혀 있다. 이 두가지 요소들은 더 심층적인 어떤 것과 연결되어있는데, 노동자계급은 오늘날 패배당하지 않았고 여전히 자본주의에 대항해 그들 자신의 이해를 위해 투쟁에 나설 수 있다는 사실이 바로 그것이다.

 

 

노동자계급이 직면한 위험

 

이는 혁명으로의 그 어떤 자동적 현상이 존재함을 의미하는가? 아니다, 전혀 그렇지 않다. 노동자계급의 혁명은 도대체가 결코 '자동적 현상'이 될 수 없는데, 이 혁명은 과거의 그어떤 혁명보다도 더 높은 의식수준을 요구하기 때문이다. 그것은, 인간이 처음으로 연대원칙이 중심에 서 있는 그러한 한 사회에서 그들 자신의 생산과 분배에 대한 통제를 넘겨받는 바로 그 순간에 다름 아니다. 그래서 이 혁명은 점점 더 대대적으로 되어가는 일련의 투쟁들에 의해서만 준비될 수 있고, 그러한 투쟁은 다시 더 깊고 더 넓은 계급의식을 불러일으키게 된다.

 

1960년대 말 위기의 최근 시기가 시작된 이래, 노동자계급의 많은 주요한 투쟁들이 있었다. 68년 5월 프랑스에서의 사건들이 유발했던 국제적인 투쟁물결에서부터 1980년 폴란드에서의 대중파업들과 1980년대 영국 광산노동자파업에 이르기까지. 비록1990년대에 계급투쟁의 오랜 역류가 있었지만, 지난 몇년동안에, 그들에게 그 어떤 미래도 제공할 능력이 없는 현 사회질서에 대해 적극적으로 '분노하는' (스페인어 개념대로 말하자면) 새로운 세대가 등장했다. 튀니지, 이집트, 그리스, 스페인, 이스라엘 등등에서의 투쟁들에서 '혁명' 의 생각은 진지한 토론주제가 되었다. 1968년 파리, 1969년 밀라노의 거리들에서 그당시 그랬던 것처럼.

 

그러나 당장 이 생각은 아직 매우 혼란스럽고 막연하다. '혁명'은, 가장 분명하게는 튀니지와 이집트의 경우에서, 또 지금 리비아가 그런 것처럼 지배계급의 일부분으로부터 그 다른 한 부분으로의 권력의 단순한 이동정도로 이해되기 쉽다. 그리고 최근의 운동들에서, 지배체제에 대항한 투쟁은 계급투쟁임을, 즉 지배계급 전체에 대항한 노동자계급의 투쟁임을 분명히 해야 함을 파악한 것은 소수에 불과했다. 40여년간의 위기 이후 특히 자본주의의 주요국가 노동자계급은 1960년대말과 같은 모습을 더이상 띠지 않는다. 거대한 산업기지들과 강력한 계급투쟁의 집중지들은 사방으로 분산되었다. 전 세대가 지속적인 불안정과 실업의 원자화의 영향을 받았다. 노동자계급의 가장 절망적인 층들은 범죄와 허무주의 또는 종교적 근본주의에 빠져들 위험에 처해있다.

 

요컨대, 자본주의 사회의 길고 점점 더 첨예해지는 쇠퇴과정으로 인해, 노동자계급은 계급정체성을 재획득하고 사회의 지도력을 넘겨받아 그 사회를 새로운 방향으로 이끌 수 있다는 자신감을 형성하는 능력에 있어서 가장 심각하고 부정적인 영향을 받을 수 있다. 그리고 자본주의 착취에 대항해 투쟁하는 노동자계급의 모범이 없이는, 체제의 불평등하고 억압적이며 부패한 본질에 대항한 무수한 분노의 반응들이 있을 지언정, 그 자체만으로는 그 어떤 출구도 만들어낼 수 없다. 몇몇 반응들은 올여름 영국의 예에서처럼, 폭동, 봉기 및 수많은 약탈의 형태를 띨 지도 모른다... 세계의 다른 지역에서는 정당한 분노의 분출들이 지배계급에 의해 인도되어, 리비아에서 보여지듯이 제국주의의 한 진영에 대항해 다른 한 진영을 지지하는 용도로 투입될 수도 있다.

 

가장 비관적인 시나리오는, 피착취자들의 투쟁이 무의미하고 자기파괴적인 행동들로 분산되어버리고, 이때 노동자계급 전체가 너무 원자화되고 너무나 분열되어버려서 하나의 진정한 사회적 힘으로 출현할 수 없게되어 버리는 것이다. 이 시나리오가 실현된다면, 아무것도 자본주의가 우리 모두를 심연에 빠뜨리는 것을 막을 수 없을 것이다. 자본주의는 세계전쟁의 전개가 없이도 충분히 그렇게 할 수 있을 것이다. 그러나 우리는 아직 그 지점에 도달하지 않았다. 그와는 반대로, 새세대 노동자들은 경제적 붕괴, 제국주의적 충돌, 환경파괴라는 자본주의의 미래에 수동적으로 그리고 아무 저항없이 이용당할 용의가 전혀 없다는 많은 암시들이 존재하고, 이 새세대가 노동자계급의 더 나이든 세대들과, 자본주의로부터 생존의 위협을 받는 모든 이들을 자신들 주변으로 끌어모을 수 있다는 증후들이 존재한다.

 

<세계혁명>, 2011년 9월 1일

 

 

 

 

 

Economic depression, war, social decay: Only the class struggle offers a way out

 

 

 

 

The dramatic worsening of the world economic crisis over the summer gives us a clear indication that the capitalist system really is on its last legs. The ‘debt crisis’ has demonstrated the literal bankruptcy not only of the banks, but of entire states; and not only the states of weak economies like Greece or Portugal but key countries of the Eurozone and on top of it all, the most powerful economy in the world: the USA.

 

And if the crisis is global, it is also historic. The mountain of debt that has become so visible over the last few years is only the consequence of capitalism trying to postpone or hide the economic crisis which surfaced as far back as the late 1960s and early 70s. And as today’s ‘recession’ reveals its real face as a genuine depression, we should recognise that this is really the same underlying crisis as the one which paralysed production in the 1930s and tipped the world towards imperialist war. A crisis expressing the historical obsolescence of the capitalist system.

 

The difference between today’s depression and that of the 1930s is that capitalism today has run out of choices. In the 1930s, the ruling class was able to offer its own barbaric solution to the crisis: mobilising society for imperialist war and re-dividing the world market. This re-organisation created the conditions for launching the ‘boom’ of the 50s and 60s. This was an option at that time, partly because world war did not yet automatically imply the destruction of capitalism itself, and there was still room for new imperialist masters to emerge in the aftermath of the war. But it was an option above all because the working class in those days had tried and failed to make its revolution (after the First World War) and had been plunged into the worst defeat in its history, at the hands of Stalinism, fascism, and democracy.

 

Today world war is only an option in the most abstract theoretical sense. In reality, the road to a global imperialist war is obstructed by the fact that, in the wake of the collapse of the old two-bloc arrangement, capitalism today is unable to forge any stable imperialist alliances. It’s also obstructed by the absence of any unifying ideology capable of persuading the majority of the exploited in the central capitalist countries that this system is worth fighting and dying for. Both these elements are linked to something deeper: the fact that the working class today has not been defeated and is still capable of fighting for its own interests against the interests of capital.

 

Dangers facing the working class

Does this mean that we heading by some automatic process towards revolution? Not at all. The revolution of the working class can never be ‘automatic’ because it requires a higher level of consciousness than any past revolution in history. It is nothing less than the moment where human beings first assume control of their own production and distribution, in a society with relations of solidarity at its heart. It can therefore only be prepared by increasingly massive struggles which generate a wider and deeper class consciousness.

 

Since the latest phase of the crisis first raised its head in the late 60s, there have been many important struggles of the working class, from the international wave sparked off by the events of May 1968 in France to the mass strikes in Poland in 1980 and the miners’ strike in Britain in the mid-80s. And even though there was a long retreat in the class struggle during the 1990s, the last few years have shown that there is now a new generation which is becoming actively ‘indignant’ (to use the Spanish term) about the failure of the present social order to offer it any future. In the struggles in Tunisia, Egypt, Greece, Spain, Israel and elsewhere, the idea of ‘revolution’ has become a serious topic for discussion, just as it did in the streets of Paris in 1968 or Milan in 1969.

 

But for the moment this idea remains very confused: ‘revolution’ can easily be mistaken for the mere transfer of power from one part of the ruling class to another, as we saw most clearly in Tunisia and Egypt, and as we are now seeing in Libya. And within the recent movements, it is only a minority which sees that the struggle against the current system has to declare itself openly as a class struggle, a struggle of the proletariat against the entire ruling class.


After four decades of crisis, the working class, especially in the central countries of capitalism, no longer even has the same shape that it had in the late 60s. Many of the most important concentrations of industry and of class militancy have been dispersed to the four winds. Whole generations have been affected by permanent insecurity and the atomisation of unemployment. The most desperate layers of the working class are in danger of falling into criminality, nihilism, or religious fundamentalism.

 

In short, the long, cumulative decay of capitalist society can have the most profoundly negative effects on the ability of the proletariat to regain its class identity and to develop the confidence that it is capable of taking society in a new direction. And without the example of a working class struggle against capitalist exploitation, there can be many angry reactions against the unjust, oppressive, corrupt nature of the system, but they will not be able to offer a way forward. Some may take the form of rioting and looting with no direction, as we have seen in Britain over the summer. In some parts of the world legitimate rage against the rulers can even be dragged into serving the needs of one bourgeois faction or one imperialist power against another, as we are seeing in Libya.

 

In the most pessimistic scenario, the struggle of the exploited will be dissipated in futile and self-defeating actions and the working class as a whole will be too atomised, too divided to constitute itself into a real social force. If this happens, there will be nothing to stop capitalism from dragging us all towards the abyss, which it is perfectly capable of doing without organising a world war. But we have not yet reached that point. On the contrary, there is plenty of evidence that a new generation of proletarians is not going to let itself be pulled passively into a capitalist future of economic collapse, imperialist conflict and ecological breakdown, and that it is capable of rallying to its banners the previous generations of the working class and all those whose lives are being blighted by capital.  

 

WR 1/9/11

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

혁명당과 자발성에 대한 문제의식 1

  • 분류
    잡기장
  • 등록일
    2011/09/21 15:00
  • 수정일
    2011/09/21 17:06
  • 글쓴이
    자유로운 영혼
  • 응답 RSS

 

혁명당과 자발성에 대한 문제의식

-레닌을 넘어 다시 맑스의 이해로 돌아와야 한다.

 

 

이란 노동자계급 스스로는 공산주의 의식과 조직을 창출할 수 없기 때문에, 노동자계급의 외부에서 도입해야 하는 그 어떤 것이 아니다. 오히려 은 계급의 표현이자, 공산주의와 자신을 동일시하고 공산주의를 위해 행동하려 하는 사람들의 공산주의 의식의 생산으로 이해되어야 한다.

 

즉, 공산주의자당은 계급투쟁의 역사 속에서 노동자계급으로부터 자발적으로 창출되는 공산주의 의식의 표현이다.  공산주의 의식으로 무장한 공산주의자들은 항상 프롤레타리아 전체의 이해관계와 프롤레타리아 운동 전체의 이익을 대변하기 때문에, 실천적으로 가장 단호하고 늘 앞서있는 부분이며, 이론적으로도 운동을 총체적으로 바라보며 대중보다 앞서 통찰한다.  따라서 당 건설 초기에는 어떠한 강요나 엄격한 규율에 의해서가 아니라  스스로 공산주의자로서의 신념과 실천을 담지한 혁명가들에 의해 당 조직이 창출된다,

 

이러한 명제는 혁명당을 건설하는 실제적인 전제 조건으로 프롤레타리아트 대중의 자발적 투쟁과, 당 강령의 생산과 명확화에 대한 필요를 제기한다.  프롤레타리아 투쟁의 부활 없이, 강령으로 표현되는 공산주의 의식의 명확화 없이 당 건설은 불가능한 것이다.

 

따라서 자발성과 의식성의 문제를 늘 적대시하면서 충돌시키는 레닌주의적 전위당 노선은 자본주의 쇠퇴의 시기(자본의 총체적 지배시기-이데올로기를 포함한) 대중행동의 자발성을 억누르거나 조직노동자 위주(자본주의 체제와 타협하면서 살아남은)의 퇴보하는 당 조직의 위험성이 있다. 반대로 계급정당, 대중정당 노선은 계급의 혁명적 의식을 방어하지 못해 계급의식이 혁명적으로 진전되는 것을 철저히 차단하거나 계급의식을 갉아먹는다.

 

혁명당을 건설하려는 동지들!  100년 전 러시아 볼셰비끼의 영광을 동일하게 재현하려는 무모한 시도도, 진보정당/노동자당을 흔들거나 눈치 보면서 떡고물이라도 얻어먹으려는 기생적 시도도 당장 집어치워야 한다. 여전히 변하지 않는 것은 혁명의 주체는 노동자계급 자신이라는 사실이다.

 

다시 노동자계급의 주체성(자립성)과 계급의식의 문제에 집중하라!!

 

 

*이에 대한 문제의식은 (카마트, 1961, 「당 형식의 기원과 역할」)을 참고할 것

  원문은  http://cafe.daum.net/leftcommunist/QerV/1

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크

나탈리야 트로츠키- 제4인터내셔널과의 결별 선언 (트로츠키주의 우파에게2)

 

나탈리야 트로츠키(Natalya Trotsky)- 제4인터내셔널과의 결별 선언

 

나탈리아 셰도바 트로츠키

 

멕시코, DF. 1951년 5월9일

 

 

 

동지들,

여러분들은 내가 여러분들과 과거 5, 6년 동안, 전쟁이 끝나기 이전부터 그 이후로 계속, 정치적으로 동의하지 않았음을 잘 알고 있습니다. 여러분들이 근래의 중요한 사건들에 대해 취한 입장은 여러분들은 여러분들이 일찍이 저지른 오류를 수정하는 대신 그것들을 끝까지 관철시키고 심화시켜왔음을 제게 보여주었습니다. 저는 여러분들의 선택에 대해, 더 이상 침묵하거나 개인적 항의자로 남아있을 수 없는 지점에 이르렀다고 생각합니다. 저는 이제 제 의견을 공식적으로 표현해야만 합니다.

 

제가 앞으로 나아갈 발걸음은 무덤과 같았고, 제게는 중대하고 어려운 것이었으며, 저는 오직 진심으로 후회할 수밖에 없습니다. 하지만 이제 다른 길은 없습니다. 제게 깊은 고통을 줬던 문제에 대한 크나큰 심사수고와 망설임 끝에, 저는 여러분에게, 제가 여러분의 수준에 더 이상 머무를 수 없을 정도로 의견이 일치하지 않는다는 것을 공개적으로 이야기하는 것 외에 다른 길은 없다고 봅니다.

 

제가 이렇게 마지막 행동을 하는 이유는 여러분이 알고 있습니다. 여기서 저는 이것에 익숙하지 않은 동지들에게만 간단히 되풀이하고자 합니다. 기본적으로 중요한 차이만 언급하고 그들과 관련 있거나 그로부터 도출되는 일상 정책 문제에 대한 차이는 다루지 않겠습니다.

 

낡고 오래된 도식화 탓에, 여러분들은 스탈린주의 국가를 계속 노동자 국가로 취급하고 있습니다. 저는 이에 대해 여러분들에게 동의하지도 않고, 동의할 수도 없습니다.

 

실제적으로 폭력적 스탈린주의 관료주의에 대한 싸움이 시작된 후, 매년, L.D 트로츠키는 정권이 우경화되고 있으며, 그것은 지체된 세계혁명의 상황, 그리고 러시아의 모든 정치적 입장이 관료주의에 포획된 상황 하에서 그러하다고 반복해서 말했습니다. 다시, 그는 러시아에서의 스탈린주의의 강화가 노동자계급의 경제적, 정치적, 사회적 지위를 악화시키게 했고, 전제적 특권적 귀족사회의 승리로 이끌었다고 지적했습니다. 이 조류가 계속된다면, 혁명이 자본주의의 종말과 부흥에 이르러서야 성취될 것이라고 그는 말했습니다.

 

불운하게도 그것은 새롭고, 기대하지 않은 형태로 정말 그렇게 되었습니다. 세계에는 그렇게 사회주의의 신뢰할만한 이념과 그 담지자가, 야만적으로 사냥당한 곳은 거의 없습니다. 혁명이 스탈린주의에 의해 완전히 파괴되었다는 것은 모든 이에게 명백해야 합니다. 여러분들은 형언할 수조차 없는 이러한 체제 하에서 러시아는 아직도 노동자 국가라고 이야기 합니다. 나는 이를 사회주의에 대한 타격이라고 봅니다. 스탈린주의와 스탈린주의 국가는 노동자 국가나 사회주의와는 어떤 공통점도 없습니다. 그들은 노동자계급과 사회주의의 최악의, 최고로 위험한 적입니다.

 

여러분은 이제 전쟁 동안, 그리고 그 이후 스탈린주의가 지배를 확립한 동유럽 국가들도 마찬가지로 노동자 국가라고 주장합니다. 이것은 스탈린주의가 혁명적 사회주의자로서의 역할을 수행했다고 이야기하는 것과 같습니다. 이에 대해서 나는 여러분에게 동의하지도 않고, 동의할 수도 없습니다.

 

전쟁 이후, 심지어 전쟁이 끝나기 전에도, 동유럽 국가들에서는 혁명적 대중운동이 올라오고 있었습니다. 그러나 권력을 차지한 것은 대중이 아니었고,  그들의 투쟁으로 건설된 국가는 노동자 국가가 아니었습니다. 권력을 획득한 것은 스탈린주의 반혁명 세력이었으며, 그것은 노동대중과 그들의 혁명적 투쟁, 그리고 혁명적 열망들을 질식시킴으로써 크레믈린의 가신들에게 이들 국가를 넘겨 버렸습니다.

 

스탈린주의 관료주의가 이런 국가들에서 노동자 국가를 세웠다고 생각하면서, 그들에게 여러분은 진보적이고 심지어 혁명적인 역할을 부여합니다. 이 끔찍한 잘못을 노동자 전위에 선전함으로써, 여러분은 사회주의 혁명의 세계 당으로서의 기본적인 존재 이유를 제4인터내셔널에서 부정합니다. 과거에는, 우리는 언제나 그 용어가 어떤 의미에서이건 스탈린주의를 반혁명적 세력으로 취급했습니다. 여러분은 더 이상 그러지 않습니다. 그러나 저는 계속 그러합니다.

 

1932년 그리고 1933년, 스탈린주의자들은 염치없는 히틀러주의와의 협정을 정당화하기 위해, 파시즘의 지배 이후, 그리고 그들 통해 사회주의가 오기 때문에 파시스트가 권력을 잡는 것은 거의 문제가 되지 않는다고 선언했습니다. 사회주의 사상과 사회주의 정신없는 오직 인간성을 잃은 짐승들은 이런 방식으로 논쟁할 수 있습니다. 이제 비록 혁명적 목적이 여러분들에게 생기를 준다고 할지라도, 여러분들은 유럽에서 승리한 전제적 스탈린주의의 반동이 마침내 사회주의로 가는 길 중 하나라고 계속해서 주장합니다. 이 관점은 결국 우리 운동에 의해 견지되고, 제가 끊임없이 공유하고자 하는 가장 심오한 신념과 타협할 수 없음을 보여줍니다.

 

유고슬라비아의 티토 정권 문제에 있어서 저는 여러분들의 의견에 동의할 수 없습니다. 혁명가들의, 심지어는 민주주의자들의 동조와 지원은, 유고슬라비아 주민들을 속박시켜 그들 나라를 가신으로 만들려는 모스크바의 전략에 대해, 확고한 저항을 하는 바로 그 유고슬라비아 주민들에게 가야 합니다. 모든 이익들은 유고슬라비아 정권이 인민들에게 제공해야 하는 승인으로 얻어져야 합니다. 그러나 여러분들의 모든 압박은 우리 운동의 전통과 원칙과는 전혀 관계가 없는 티토주의 관료주의의 변명할 수 없는 이상화에 기여하고 있습니다.

 

이 관료주의는 그저 새로운 형태의 스탈린주의 관료주의의 모조일 뿐입니다. 이것은 GPU(소련의 국가정치보안부. 나중에 KGB로 바뀌었다)의 사상과 정치와 윤리에 길들여졌습니다. 그 정권은 스탈린 정권과 근본적인 면에서 전혀 차이가 없습니다. 유고슬라브 인민의 혁명적 리더십이 이 관료주의로부터 발전된다거나, 그에 저항하는 투쟁의 과정이라고 믿거나 혹은 가르치려는 것은 어처구니가 없습니다.

 

무엇보다도 여러분들을 지지할 수 없는 가장 큰 이유는 여러분들이 스스로 저질렀던 전쟁에 대한 입장입니다. 인류를 위협하는 3차 세계대전은 가장 어려운 문제, 가장 복잡한 상황, 막중한 결정을 해야 할 혁명운동에 직면하고 있습니다. 우리들은 오직 가장 진지하고 가장 자유로운 토론을 거쳐서 입장을 선택할 수 있습니다. 그러나 최근 몇 년의 모든 사건을 접하면서, 여러분들은 스탈린주의 국가를 방어하기 위하여 모든 운동을 주창하고 서약하고 있습니다. 심지어 여러분들은 고통 받는 한국 인민들이 견뎌내는 전쟁에서 스탈린주의 군대를 지원하고 있습니다. 저는 이러한 여러분들에게 동의하지도 않고, 동의할 수도 없습니다.

 

1927년으로 거슬러 올라가, 트로츠키는 정치국에서 스탈린이 던진 불명예스러운 질문에 대한 답으로 그의 견해를 다음과 같이 이야기했습니다.

 

“사회주의 조국을 위하여, 그렇습니다! 그러나 스탈린주의 정권을 위해서는 결코 아닙니다!”

 

그것이 1927년이었습니다. 23년이나 지난 오늘날, 스탈린은 사회주의 조국엔 그 무엇도 남기지 않았습니다. 스탈린주의 독재로 인민들을 노예화시키고 타락시키는 것으로 그것은 대체되었던 것입니다. 이것이 여러분들이 이미 한반도에서 방어하고 있는 전쟁을 방어하기 위하여 제안하는 국가입니다.

 

저는 여러분들이 얼마나 자주 스탈린주의를 비판하고 그와의 싸움을 반복했는지 잘 압니다. 그러나 사실은, 여러분들의 비판과 싸움은 그 가치를 잃었으며, 스탈린주의 국가의 방어라는 여러분들의 입장에 의해 결정되어 있고, 그에 종속되어 있기 때문에, 그러한 것은 어떤 결과도 낼 수 있습니다.  누구든 이 야만적인 억압의 정권을 방어하려는 자들은, 그 동기에 관계없이 사회주의와 국제주의의 원칙을 포기하는 것입니다.

 

SWP의 최근 대회로부터 제게 온 메시지에서, 여러분들은 트로츠키의 생각이 여러분들의 안내자라고 쓰고 있습니다. 전 이글을 읽으며 매우 비통한 심정이었음을 밝힙니다. 위에서 썼던 것에서 여러분들이 보셨듯이, 저는 여러분들의 정치에서 그의 사상을 보지 않습니다. 저는 이러한 사상에 확신이 있습니다. 저는 현대 상황을 타개할 수 있는 유일한 길은 사회혁명, 즉 세계 프롤레타리아트의 자기 해방 뿐이라고 여전히 그렇게 생각합니다.

 

 

 

 

세도바 트로츠키의 편지에 대하여  -공산주의 노동자 조직(CWO)

 

 

트로츠키의 미망인인 나탈리야가 트로츠키주의의 운동과 결별할 때 발표한 상명을 우리는 재발간한다. 그녀는 그들이 스탈린주의에 대해 면책권을 주는 것이 프롤레타리아 혁명의 확실한 포기라는 결과를 초래했다고 보았다. 그녀가 언급한 두 가지 결정적 요소는 동유럽 모스크바 지배의 국가들을 변형된 노동자 국가의 범주에 넣은 트로츠키주의자들의 결정과 러시아, 중국, 그리고 북한의 스탈린주의자들을 한국 전쟁 기간 동안 지원한 것이다.

 

셰도바 트로츠키의 편지는 공산주의 노동자 조직(CWO)과 혁명당 국제서기국(IBRP *CWO는 IBRP의 한축으로 영국의 섹션이다)이 충실한 국제주의 흐름의 전통과 매우 다른 전제를 기반으로 하고 있다. 비록 그녀가 명확하게 스탈린주의 국가가 노동자 국가가 아님은 지적했지만, 트로츠키주의의 환상의 근원을 밝혀내는 데는 실패하고 있다. 매우 간단하게도 그 뿌리는 트로츠키 자신에게로 되돌아가기 때문이다. 1927년 트로츠키가 사회주의자 조국을 지원하기로 선언한 것은 그가 러시아 공산당과 ,코민테른의 지도자들 사이에 있었던 분파투쟁 동안 스탈린주의에게 일찍이 줬던 면죄부를 표현해준다. 셰도바의 반파시즘에 대한 은연중의 지지와, 트로츠키주의자들의 1930년대의 통일전선주의의 지지는, 명확하게, 셰도바가 트로츠키주의의 반혁명적 입장의 근원을 폭로하기 위한 충분히 심도 있는 비판을 하지 못했음을 보여준다.

 

그럼에도 불구하고, 우리는 트로츠키주의자들이 자신들의 기록에 접촉하러 오는 이들에게 숨기길 바라는 역사적 기록에 보태기 위해 그 편지가 재출간될 가치가 있다고 본다. 그 문서는 트로츠키주의 운동이 혁명적 이론과 실천으로부터 동떨어져 진행해 온 그 거리를 결론적으로 보여준다. 그 성명이 쓰인 이후 반세기동안, 트로츠키주의자들은 더욱 더 반혁명의 궤도를 따라 계속 나아갔다.  이 편지에서 언급한 SWP는 그 시기 제4인터내셔널의 미국 섹션인 당으로 스스로를 제4인터내셔널에 동조하는 섹션으로 기술하면서 미국 법에 동조했다. 1980년대 동안 그들은 쿠바 카스트로 정권의 치어리더가 되기 위해 트로츠키주의자 사이에서 더 많은 분열을 초래했다. 셰도바 트로츠키의 초기 성명 직전 몇 년간 영국의 트로츠키 운동내의 수많은 분열중의 하나였던 같은 이름의 영국 기반조직인 SWP와 혼동해서는 안 된다.

 

 

 

 

트로츠키주의의 반파시즘에 대하여  -CWO

 

국제주의자들에게, 파시즘은 제국주의의 산물이다. 그것은 혁명적 투쟁의 패배에 따른 심각한 위기의 결과로 프롤레타리아트가 지불한 대가의 일부다. 그러나 결코 20세기 부르주아 민주주의(대도시 지역 국가들에서의 제국주의 지배가 선호한 형태)가 제국주의 형성보다 덜한 작은 것이라고 믿는 것은 절대 아니다. 파시즘과 제국주의의 민주주의적 형태 둘 다에 대한 역사적 해결책은 노동자계급의 혁명이다. 트로츠키주의자를 위한 것이 아닌!

 

몇 번이고 되풀이하여, 트로츠키주의자들은 예를 들면 훨씬 더 많은 흑인들이 민주주의 영국 국가의 손에 죽어가며 고통에 신음하고 있다는 사실을 무시하며 별것 아닌 파시스트 조직의 역할을 강조하려 할 것이다. 트로츠키주의자들은 스탈린주의자, 그리고 다른 좌파 동맹과 함께 혼란의 병기고 속에서 중요한 요소로 반파시즘을 유지하기 위해 오랫동안 힘들게 싸워왔다.

 

반파시즘은 단지 노동자계급 속에 널리 퍼진, 많은 다른 부르주아지 사이에서 있는 혼란속의 하나가 아니다. 그것은 노동자계급을 2차 제국주의 전쟁으로 몰아넣은 가장 강력한 유일한 이데올로기 도구였다. 스페인 내전동안에 기반이 준비되어 있었기에, 트로츠키주의자들과 스탈린주의자들은 체계적으로 그들의 추종자들로 하여금 독일 주도의 축에 맞서 민주주의 진영에서 싸우도록 준비시켰다. 공시적인 공산당 리더십은 (1939년 9월~1941년 5월의 히틀러-스탈린 조약 동안) 그들의 외부 그리고 스탈린의 위대한 애국전쟁 동안 앵글로-러시안-아메리칸 제국주의 동맹을 외부에서 지원하는 노선으로부터의 이탈을 메우는 것이었다.

 

반파시즘은 부르주아지의 이데올로기 병기고에서 여전히 중요한 무기로 남아있다. 독재자에 저항하는 투쟁은 이라크에 반대하는 전쟁 지원을 유발시키는데 이용되었다. 클린턴과 블레어의 밀로세비치의 세르비아 정부를 비난하는 긴 연설은 제국주의의 민주적 반파시즘 용어의 많은 특징들을 이용했음을 알 수 있다. 우린 이미 어떻게 현대의 트로츠키주의자들이 전쟁 기간 중에도 하나 또는 다른 부르주아 분파를 지원하기 위해 선거를 하는지 보았다. 반파시즘 논리의 이용은, 그들의 더 큰 부르주아 형제분파들이 노동자들을 제국주의 학살로 내몰도록 입지를 넓혀주고 있다.

진보블로그 공감 버튼트위터로 리트윗하기페이스북에 공유하기딜리셔스에 북마크